The Share of Systematic Variation in Bilateral Exchange Rates

DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jofi.12587
Date01 February 2018
Published date01 February 2018
AuthorADRIEN VERDELHAN
THE JOURNAL OF FINANCE VOL. LXXIII, NO. 1 FEBRUARY 2018
The Share of Systematic Variation in Bilateral
Exchange Rates
ADRIEN VERDELHAN
ABSTRACT
Sorting countries by their dollar currency betas produces a novel cross section of
average currency excess returns. A slope factor (long in high beta currencies and
short in low beta currencies) accounts for this cross section of currency risk premia.
This slope factor is orthogonal to the high-minus-low carry trade factor built from
portfolios of countries sorted by their interest rates. The two high-minus-low risk
factors account for 18% to 80% of the monthly exchange rate movements. The two
risk factors suggest that stochastic discount factors in complete markets’ models
should feature at least two global shocks to describe exchange rates.
THE CORRELATION STRUCTURE OF BILATERAL EXCHANGE RATES can be summarized
by a small number of principal components, but those principal components
offer a purely statistical description of exchange rates and are difficult to in-
terpret in any micro- or macrofinance model. In this paper, in contrast, I report
that two currency risk factors account for a substantial share of individual
exchange rate time series. These factors are priced in currency markets and
the shares of systematic currency risk have implications for any no-arbitrage
model in international finance.
Two risk factors, namely, carry and dollar, are constructed from portfolios
of currencies. The carry factor corresponds to the change in exchange rates
between baskets of high and low interest rate currencies, while the dollar
factor corresponds to the average change in the exchange rate between the
U.S. dollar and all other currencies. All exchange rates are defined here with
respect to the U.S. dollar. I regress changes in exchange rates on the carry
factor, the same carry factor multiplied by the country-specific interest rate
difference (the latter is referred to as “conditional carry”), and the dollar factor.
The change in bilateral exchange rate on the left-hand side of these regressions
is measured between tand t+1; on the right-hand side, the carry and dollar
Adrien Verdelhan is with MIT Sloan and NBER. The author thanks the Editor, Ken Sin-
gleton, two anonymous referees, as well as Andrew Atkeson, Nittai Bergman, John Campbell,
Francesca Carrieri, Mike Chernov, Martin Evans, Emmanuel Farhi, Tarek Hassan, Chris Jones,
Pab Jotikasthira, Thomas Knox, Leonid Kogan, Ralph Koijen, David Laibson, Hanno Lustig, Mat-
teo Maggiori, Nelson Mark, Philippe Mueller, Jun Pan, Tarun Ramadorai, Steve Ross, Barbara
Rossi, Nick Roussanov, Lucio Sarno, Piet Sercu, Chris Telmer, Jiang Wang, Ken West, and partic-
ipants at many seminars and conferences for helpful comments and discussions. I have read the
Journal of Finance’s disclosure policy and have no conflicts of interest to disclose.
DOI: 10.1111/jofi.12587
375
376 The Journal of Finance R
factors also correspond to changes between tand t+1, while the domestic and
foreign interest rates are known at date t. The carry and dollar factors do not
include the bilateral exchange rate that is the dependent variable.
The factor regressions offer a novel picture of bilateral exchange rate move-
ments. Both factors appear highly significant. With the carry factors, the ad-
justed R2s range from 0% to 23% among developed countries at the monthly
frequency over the 1983 to 2010 sample. While a lot of research focuses on the
carry trade, the dollar factor appears to be a more important driver of exchange
rates. When the two factors are combined, the adjusted R2s range from around
20% to 90% in developed countries and from 10% to 75% among developing
countries with floating currencies. The distribution of R2s on the factor regres-
sions is quite stable across frequencies; similar distributions appear at daily,
monthly, quarterly, and annual frequencies. The substantial R2s of the factor
regressions do not imply that bilateral exchange rates are easy to forecast: the
corresponding regressions use contemporaneous variables, not predictive ones.
Large R2s can naturally be obtained by using three or more principal compo-
nents. The dollar factor is actually close to the first principal component, while
the carry factor is different from any of them—the information contained in
short-term interest rates matters. Both factors deliver a more stable descrip-
tion of exchange rates than the principal components. More crucially, principal
components do not imply that risks are priced. In contrast, both the carry and
the dollar factors are priced in currency markets. They are risk factors in the
asset pricing sense, consistent with the logic of an Euler equation.
The risk-based interpretation of the carry factor is well known. Previous
research on currency portfolios shows that the carry factor accounts for the
cross section of currency excess returns sorted by interest rates: covariances of
the carry factor with currency returns align with the cross section of average
excess returns. A consistent result appears here on individual currencies: the
higher the interest rate, the larger the loading on the carry risk factor. This is
the risk-based explanation of the classic currency carry trade.
This paper shows that the dollar factor also has a risk-based interpretation.
The price of dollar risk cannot be estimated precisely from portfolios of countries
sorted by interest rates because these portfolios all load in the same way on the
dollar factor. Instead, I build portfolios of countries sorted by their time-varying
exposures to the dollar factor (i.e., dollar betas). After transaction costs, the low
dollar beta portfolio offers an average log excess return of just 0.6% per year
for investors who go long foreign currencies when the average forward discount
(average foreign minus U.S. interest rate) is positive and short otherwise. The
high dollar beta portfolio offers an average log excess return of 5.8% for similar
investments, implying a large Sharpe ratio of almost 0.6. Conditioning on the
average forward discount, covariances of the dollar factor with portfolio returns
account for this new cross section of average excess returns, while covariances
with the carry factor do not. The estimated price of dollar risk is significant
and close to the mean of the factor, as implied by the absence of arbitrage.
The key pricing information is contained in a long-minus-short risk factor,
built from the same set of portfolios used as test assets as the difference in
The Share of Systematic Variation in FX 377
exchange rates between high and low dollar beta portfolios. The loadings of
dollar beta portfolios on this long-minus-short risk factor are significant and
vary monotonically across portfolios. I refer to the difference in exchange rates
between high and low dollar beta portfolios as the global component of the
dollar factor. It is highly correlated (0.85) with the dollar factor itself but its
correlation with the carry factor is statistically insignificant.
Overall, by building portfolios of currency returns, one can extract two risk
factors defined as differences in exchange rate changes, and thus immune to
U.S.-specific shocks: the carry factor and the global component of the dollar
factor. These two variables describe bilateral exchange rates expressed in U.S.
dollars or in different units. Regressions of changes in bilateral exchange rates
on the two high-minus-low risk factors deliver R2s between 18% and 83% for
exchange rates defined in U.S. dollars. This is the key result of the paper,
as only “dollar-neutral” explanatory variables are used in these regressions.
The same variables describe exchange rates defined in other currencies, for
example, Japanese yen and U.K. pounds. The R2s are lower but still range
from 18% to 46% for yen-based exchange rates and from 6% to 48% for pound-
based exchange rates. The loadings on the global component of the dollar factor
are significant in 20 out of 26 regressions. If the factors were capturing country-
specific shocks, they would not describe currencies in other units. The empirical
findings in this paper suggest that global shocks are key to describing exchange
rates.
The economic source of those global shocks is an open question. At the annual
frequency, the global component of the dollar tends to be low when developed
countries are close to the troughs of their business cycles, as measured by
the OECD turning points. The dollar risk could thus be interpreted as global
macroeconomic level risk, while carry shocks appear more related to volatil-
ity and uncertainty.1Of course, this tentative interpretation does not exclude
others based on shocks to, for example, liquidity, intermediaries’ wealth, mon-
etary policies, international trade, or international capital flows. The different
potential sources and interpretations of those global shocks, as well as the un-
derlying economic sources of the differences in country betas, are potentially
fruitful research avenues. As an initial step in that research agenda, I show
in a qualitative reduced-form model that two kinds of global shocks to the
stochastic discount factors (SDFs) are necessary to describe exchange rates.
In the tradition of Frachot (1996), Backus, Foresi, and Telmer (2001), and
Hodrick and Vassalou (2002), I start from the law of motion of lognormal SDFs.
In the model, each log SDF is driven by country-specific and two world shocks.
When markets are complete, log changes in exchange rates correspond to the
differences between domestic and foreign log SDFs. The volatilities of the SDF
shocks are time-varying to account for the forward premium puzzle. For the
sake of clarity, the main text focuses on a special case of the model, while the
1The carry factor can be proxied by measures of global volatility on equity (Lustig, Roussanov,
and Verdelhan,2011) oron currency markets (Menkhoff et al., 2012a), or by measuresof downside
equity risk (Lettau, Maggiori, and Weber,2014).

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT