The Role of Public Information in Corporate Social Responsibility

AuthorJuan‐José Ganuza,Aleix Calveras
Date01 December 2016
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jems.12156
Published date01 December 2016
The Role of Public Information in Corporate Social
Responsibility
ALEIX CALVERAS
Department of Business Economics
Universitat de les Illes Balears
Cra Valldemossa Km 7 07122 Palma de Mallorca Spain
aleix.calveras@uib.es
JUAN-JOS´
EGANUZA
Department of Economics and Business
Universitat Pompeu Fabra
C/Ramon TriasFargas 25-27 08005 Barcelona Spain
juanjo.ganuza@upf.edu
Many of the attributes that make a good “socially responsible” (SR) are credence attributes that
cannot be learned by consumers either through search or experience. Consumers, then, use for
their purchasing decisions “noisy” information about these attributes obtained from potentially
contradictory channels (media, advertisement, NGOs). In this paper we model such informational
framework and show the positive relationship between the accuracy of the information transmitted
to consumers and corporate social responsibility. We also show that a firm may be tempted to
add noise to the information channel (through lobbying of the media), which might reduce the
supply of the SR attributes and even harm the firm itself (with lower profits). It might then be
profitable to the firm to commit ex ante to not manipulate the information regarding the firm’s
business practices (e.g., with a partnership with an NGO). Finally, we extend our model to a
competition framework endogenizing the number of firms active in the SR segment. We show
both that in more transparent markets a larger number of firms will be SR, and that in a market
with more intense competition, a higher degree of transparency is required in order to sustain a
given number of SR firms.
1. Introduction
Many of the attributes that make a good or a service “green” or, moregenerally, socially
responsible (SR), are credence attributes, not directly observable by consumers, who
cannot learn about them either through search or experience (Nelson, 1970; Tirole, 1988;
Baron, 2011). Examples of such attributes are numerous: the conditions under which
the product is produced (including any externalities associated with production, for
example, pollution and how workers are treated and how well they are paid), hidden
hazards associated with consumption of the product, etc.
We are grateful for comments by the co-editor, two anonymous referees, seminar participants at FEDEA
and Universidad de Salamanca, and the conference attendees at the JEI (Madrid) and the EARIE conference
(Istambul). Naturally, all errors are ours. Aleix Calveras gratefully acknowledges financial support of the
Spanish Ministry of Economics and Competitiveness under grant ECO2013-48496-C4-1-R. Juan-Jos´
e Ganuza
gratefully acknowledges the support of the Barcelona GSE Research, the government of Catalonia, and the
Spanish Ministry of Education and Science Through Project ECO 2011-28965 and ECO2014-59225-P.
C2015 Wiley Periodicals, Inc.
Journal of Economics & Management Strategy, Volume25, Number 4, Winter 2016, 990–1017
Public Information in Corporate Social Responsibility 991
This asymmetry of information between a firm and its customers (and other stake-
holders) regarding the firm’s business practices poses a threatto the viability of corporate
social responsibility (CSR).1CSR is mainly driven by demand of “conscious” consumers
(namely, consumers who value one of these SR credence attributes, and are willing to
pay a higher price for a good that includes them) and, thus, the level and accuracy of
the information available to consumers is key.2Absent credibleinformation, the market
might fail to provide the credence attributes valued by consumers: if consumers are un-
certain about the attributes of the good, then they might not be willing to pay a premium
for it and, thus, firms will not supply such attributes in the first place (Akerloff, 1974).
Thus, the level of credible information available to consumers (firm’s stakeholders in
general) with respect to firm’s business practices is key in the development of CSR. And
the purpose of this paper is precisely to study the role of informational issues in the
promotion of CSR. More specifically, we want to analyze:
(i) In which way the level of information accuracy (or lack of it) in the market impacts
in the ability and incentives of firms to invest in corporate social responsibility. We
consider that consumers receive information from several channels (with potentially
contradictory messages; e.g., from the media, NGOs, and firms themselves) and that
they aggregate it in a noisy signal. It is thus important to assess in which way the
quality of the signal impacts on firms’ incentives to invest in social responsibility,
and we do so considering different levels of market competition among SR firms.
(ii) How information about the behavior of the firm is produced and the incentives of
agents to provide it. The number of agents that (may) play a role in the transmission
of information to consumers on businesses’ practices is wide; in particular, we focus
on the incentives of a firm to manipulate the information provided to consumers
(through advertisement, media, etc.) and the consequences it has on CSR.
(iii) The role of regulation and, specially, other decentralized institutional arrangements
such as a firm’s partnership with an NGO, in order to promote transparency and
indirectly foster CSR.3
Our modeling framework thus allows us to discuss in which way the accuracy
of the information that consumers receive influences the incentives of firms to be SR,
specifically by investing in a clean and more expensive technology (rather than in the
standard, dirty, and cheaper one). We do the analysis first in the benchmark model in
which only a single firm may differentiate and become SR, and then also in a framework
where we endogenize the number of firms that may differentiate and become SR. When
competition in CSR is considered, in addition to the impact of market transparency,
1. By CSR, we denote those “voluntary actions that firms take over and above compliance with minimum
legal requirements, to address both its own competitive interests and the interests of the wider society” (as
defined by the UKs Department of Trade and Industry).
2. Evidence regarding the valuation by some conscious consumers on some credence attributes (and who
are willing to pay a higher price for them) can be found in relation to the labor conditions of a firm (Hiscox and
Smyth, 2009), to charity linked products (Elfenbein and McManus, 2007), or the environmental friendliness of
a product (Casadesus-Masanell et al., 2009). See also, for instance, Mohr et al., 2001, and Murray and Volgel,
1997).
3. An example of a transparency regulation is the European Union Directive 1999/94/EC which requires
car makers to inform consumers on fuel economy and CO2emissions of each car, as part of a “an overall
Community strategy aimed [ . . . ] to reduce CO2emissions, in particular those caused by passenger cars”
(EU Directive 1999/94/EC). More specifically, the labeling Directive requires the display of a label on fuel
consumption and CO2emissions on all new cars, the publication of national guides on the fuel efficiency and
emission of CO2of new cars, the display of posters at the dealerships, and the inclusion of fuel efficiency and
CO2emissions information in printed promotional literature.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT