The Relevance of Business Exit for Future Entrepreneurial Activity

Date01 March 2016
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1002/jsc.2053
AuthorJudit Albiol‐Sánchez
Published date01 March 2016
RESEARCH ARTICLE
Strat. Change 25: 151–169 (2016)
Published online in Wiley Online Library
(wileyonlinelibrary.com) DOI: 10.1002/jsc.2053
Copyright © 2016 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd.
Strategic Change: Briengs in Entrepreneurial Finance
Strategic Change
DOI: 10.1002/jsc.2053
The Relevance of Business Exit for Future
Entrepreneurial Activity1
Judit Albiol‐Sánchez
Department of Economics, Universitat Rovira i Virgili, Reus, Spain
Territories can capitalize on knowledge resulting from business exit by designing
policies that distinguish rst‐time entrepreneurs who need specic support and
information from individuals with an entrepreneurial background whose experience
might help enhance the quality of future entrepreneurial activity.
e analysis of the impact of entrepreneurial exit on macroeconomic gures is an
interesting information‐based input to promote entrepreneurship. In most coun-
tries, policymakers employ entrepreneurship as a tool for overcoming stagnating
or declining economic activity (Henry and Treanor, 2013). As a result, entrepre-
neurship has rmly entered into the agendas of policymakers, educators, practi-
tioners, and business people.
e current economic and nancial crisis faced by economies since 2008 has
triggered signicant debate among policymakers. Many researchers have noted
that the labor market experienced its deepest downturn since the post‐World War
II era (Elsby et al., 2010). In particular, this downturn has had an important
implication for entrepreneurship rates. us, in most developed and developing
countries the analysis of entrepreneurial exit has become crucial since it may
impact the conguration and level of competitiveness of local industries. Yet little
attention has been paid to the impact of entrepreneurial exits on entrepreneurial
entry decisions (DeTienne, 2010).
Fritsch and Mueller (2004) argue that market exit should be understood as a
necessary element of market selection, and this would likely result in improved
competitiveness and employment growth. Also, it is suggested that policymakers
should stop subsidizing rms to minimize the costly exit of newly created rms.
Previous research using data from the Global Entrepreneurship Monitor (GEM)
shows substantial dierences in the dynamics of entrepreneurship across economies
(Acs and Varga, 2005; Reynolds et al., 2005; Wennekers et al., 2005). Audretsch
and urik (2000, 2001, 2004) emphasize the observed correlation between entre-
preneurship rates and the level of economic development. Hence, scholars seem
1 JEL classication codes: L26, O11.
The relationship between business
exit rates and new entrepreneurial
activity evidences changes in the
conguration of the local
industrial fabric.
In developed economies,
policymakers make an excessive
use of entrepreneurship as an
instrument to channel
unemployed individuals to the
labor market.
Policies seeking to increase the
impact of necessity‐driven
entrepreneurship should target
the specic needs of these
entrepreneurs and increase their
level of human capital.
152 Judit Albiol-Sánchez
Copyright © 2016 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strategic Change
DOI: 10.1002/jsc
to agree that the level of entrepreneurial activity varies
systematically across countries (see, for example, Wit and
Winden, 1989; Blanchower and Meyer, 1994; Rees and
Shah, 2006; Grilo and urik,2008).
erefore, it is crucial to assess whether entrepreneur-
ial exit rates contribute to explain future entrepreneurial
activity across economies. is study uses GEM data to
explain whether business exits lead (or not) to a fall in
future levels of entrepreneurial activity at the country
level. To enhance estimation accuracy, the total entrepre-
neurial activity (TEA) rate and its two components –
nascent and new business activity rates – have been
analyzed. Given that entrepreneurs are heterogeneous in
their entry motivations (Reynolds et al., 2005; Ardagna
and Lusardi, 2009), the analysis distinguishes between
opportunity‐driven and necessity‐driven entrepreneurial
activity.
e data used in this study cover the period 2002–
2007 for a sample of 41 economies. e longitudinal
nature of the data allows us to accurately study the busi-
ness exit–entrepreneurial activity relationship. To the best
of our knowledge, this is the rst longitudinal study
linking exit rates to future entrepreneurial activity at the
country level.
e remainder of the study is organized as follows.
e rst section provides a brief overview of the entrepre-
neurship literature. e second section then describes the
data and the econometric methodology. e third section
presents the results, while the nal section provides con-
cluding remarks.
Literature review
Business exit
Following DeTienne (2010), business exit, understood as
the process by which entrepreneurs leave the rm they
created – either by removing themselves from the owner-
ship and decision‐making structure of the rm, shutting
down the business, or discontinuing business activity – is
a critical stage of the entrepreneurial process. Entrepre-
neurial exit not only represents the end of the rm’s
lifecycle, but also has a signicant eect on the industry
and the local economy. From an industry perspective,
entrepreneurial exit rates might represent a change in both
the competitive balance of the industry and the congura-
tion of the local industrial fabric, thus providing value to
competing rivals (Akhigbe et al., 2003).
Business exit is more than a mere liquidity‐related
event. At the territorial level, exit rates might be the ulti-
mate consequence of the recycling process of the stock of
entrepreneurial rms (DeTienne, 2010). Territories might
show high (or low) business exit rates, and these exit rates
are path dependent and inuence future decisions of
entrepreneurs. is way, the regeneration of the popula-
tion of businesses represents a mechanism to transfer
novelty to established rms, with potentially positive and
negative eects on the territory’s economy (Audretsch,
1995). New rms represent a vital space for introducing
innovations to the market (Decker and Mellewigt, 2007) –
however, market selection forces often take many of these
short‐lived rms out of the economy, thus limiting their
potential contribution. On the contrary, and against the
background of the current economic downturn, new rms
are vulnerable to market conditions, thus increasing their
likelihood of being selected out from the industry. is
way, economic turbulence might contribute to the
consolidation of high‐potential new rms, thus facilitat-
ing the regeneration of the stock of rms by displacing
established businesses (Audretsch, 1995; DeTienne,
2010).
Entry decision: opportunity and necessity motivations
e decision to become an entrepreneur is heterogeneous
among individuals, mainly because of existing dierences
in their motivation to start a business. Research in the
economics of entrepreneurship distinguishes between
opportunity and necessity entrepreneurs (e.g., Reynolds
et al., 2005; Sternberg and Wennekers, 2005; Ardagna
and Lusardi, 2009; Block and Wagner, 2010). ese

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT