The Recovery from the Great Recession: A Long, Evolving Expansion

AuthorJay C. Shambaugh,Michael R. Strain
Published date01 May 2021
Date01 May 2021
DOI10.1177/00027162211022305
Subject MatterOverview Papers
28 ANNALS, AAPSS, 695, May 2021
DOI: 10.1177/00027162211022305
The Recovery
from the Great
Recession: A
Long, Evolving
Expansion
By
JAY C. SHAMBAUGH
and
MICHAEL R. STRAIN
1022305ANN The Annals Of The American AcademyThe Recovery From The Great Recession
research-article2021
Prior to 2020, the Great Recession was the most impor-
tant macroeconomic shock to the United States’ econ-
omy in generations. Millions lost jobs and homes. At its
peak, one in ten workers who wanted a job could not
find one. On an annual basis, the economy contracted
by more than it had since the Great Depression. A slow
and steady recovery followed the Great Recession’s
official end in summer 2009, but because it was slow
and the depth of the recession so deep, it took years to
reduce slack in labor markets. But because the recovery
lasted so long, many pre-recession peaks were exceeded,
and eventually real wage growth accumulated for work-
ers across the distribution. In fact, the business cycle
(including recession and recovery) beginning in
December 2007 was one of the better periods of real
wage growth in many decades, with the bulk of that
coming in the last years of the recovery.
Keywords: recession; wage growth; business cycles;
monetary policy
Prior to 2020, the Great Recession was the
most important macroeconomic shock to
the United States’ economy in generations.
Millions lost jobs and homes. At its peak, one in
ten workers who wanted a job could not find
one.1 On an annual basis, the economy con-
tracted by more than it had since the Great
Depression. Asset prices fell sharply. Policy
interest rates hit their lowest level in history,
and deficits spiked.2,3 The jury is still out on the
severity and lasting duration of the Pandemic
Jay C. Shambaugh is a professor of economics and
international affairs at George Washington University
and a faculty research fellow at the National Bureau of
Economic Research.
Michael R. Strain is the director of economic policy
studies and Arthur F. Burns Scholar in political econ-
omy at the American Enterprise Institute and a research
fellow at the IZA Institute of Labor Economics.
NOTE: We thank Duncan Hobbs for excellent research
assistance.
Correspondence: michael.strain@aei.org
THE RECOVERY FROM THE GREAT RECESSION 29
Recession, but it would not surprise us if history remembers the Great Recession
as the more significant macroeconomic event of the two.
A slow and steady recovery followed the Great Recession’s official end in sum-
mer 2009, but because it was slow and the recession was so deep, it took years to
reduce slack in labor markets. Despite steady job growth, the share of the popu-
lation that was employed stayed well below pre-recession levels for years, and
wages grew slowly.
But because the slow-and-steady recovery lasted so long, many pre-recession
peaks were exceeded, and eventually real wage growth began to accumulate for
workers across the distribution. In fact, the business cycle (including recession
and recovery) beginning in December 2007 was one of the better periods of real
wage growth in many decades, with the bulk of its gains coming in the last years
of the recovery.
Despite eventual gains for workers, the longest expansion in U.S. history fea-
tured slow productivity growth and slower output growth than many experts
expected. It was supported by accommodative monetary policy for an extended
period. As we discuss in this article, fiscal policy was more variable, supportive
early in the recovery before pivoting to a contractionary stance, and then featur-
ing a surge of deficit spending late in the expansion.
The economic expansion following the Great Recession included the longest
streak of job growth on record. Beginning in October 2010, the economy added
jobs for 113 consecutive months. The streak ended in March 2020 when the
COVID-19 recession began.
Because the expansion was so long, it was able to go through different phases.
Early in the expansion, jobless rates remained stubbornly high, participation
rates continued falling, and wage growth was slow. Later in this article, we show
that compared to their outcomes prior to the recession, the least-educated,
lowest-wage workers in the labor market fared considerably worse than more-
educated, higher-wage workers.
But by 2014, wages began to grow faster at the median. By 2015, prime-age
labor force participation began to increase. In the last five years of the expansion,
wage growth had picked up at the bottom of the income distribution, outpacing
gains in the middle and at the top of the distribution. Employment rates for the
workers with the least education rose further above their pre-recession level than
those for college graduates. Vulnerable workers saw their labor market prospects
improve considerably. The length of the expansion—which allowed the labor
market to tighten—was critical to both bringing people back into the workforce
and seeing wage gains pushed across the income distribution.
The length of the expansion and continual job growth highlight in some sense
how long the economy had extensive labor market slack. The loss of jobs in the
first two years following the start of the recession (peaking at 8.7 million jobs),
the increase in the unemployment rate by 5.3 percentage points, and the decline
in participation were so stark during the financial crisis that there was a large
amount of labor market slack when positive job growth did begin. In addition, the
financial crisis struck when there was arguably still labor market slack following
the 2001 recession.4 The combination of the challenges monetary policy faces

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT