The Quality of Institutions and Organizational Form Decisions: Evidence from Within the Firm

Date01 June 2017
AuthorFrancine Lafontaine,Rozenn Perrigot,Nathan E. Wilson
Published date01 June 2017
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jems.12185
The Quality of Institutions and Organizational Form
Decisions: Evidence from Within the Firm
FRANCINE LAFONTAINE
Ross School of Business
University of Michigan
Ann Arbor, MI 48109
laf@umich.edu
ROZENN PERRIGOT
IGR-IAE Rennes, CREM
University of Rennes 1
35000 Rennes, France
rozenn.perrigot@univ-rennes1.fr
NATHAN E. WILSON
Federal TradeCommission, Bureau of Economics
Washington, DC 20580
nwilson@ftc.gov
In many retail and service sectors, firms have to establish a physical presence in a geographic
market to access customers there. In countries where the quality of institutions is low, this can
put assets at risk. We use data on the operations of a multinational, multibrand hotel company
to show that in environments where local institutions are weaker—as proxied mainly by the
World Bank’s Checks index—the company eschews direct ownership. Rather than increasing its
reliance on franchising, as predicted by some models, the company relies more on another form of
organization commonly used in this industry, namely management contracts. We explain these
patterns by emphasizing how the quality of the institutional environment affects the cost of using
equity-based organizational forms, per arguments in the current literature, but also the cost of
enforcing the terms of franchise contracts.
1. Introduction
Economists and business scholars have devoted much attention to understanding how
institutions affect economic behavior.An important part of this literature has focused on
the effect of institutions, broadly defined, on economy-wide growth and performance
(see, e.g., Acemoglu et al., 2001; Levchenko, 2007; Dixit, 2009; Bruhn and Gallego, 2012;
see also Acemoglu et al., 2005 for a review of the economics literature). A smaller but
growing set of papers considers the effect of institutions at a more micro level, often
by examining how multinational corporations adapt to local market conditions. One
branch of this literature has explored how factors like the rule of law (Liu et al., 2011),
The opinions expressedhere are those of the authors and not necessarily those of the Federal Trade Commission
or any of its Commissioners. Weare very grateful to the Company for giving us access to the data and to Robert
Picard for his invaluable assistance. Wealso thank participants at the International Industrial Organization, the
Midwest Economics Association, and the International Society of Franchising conferences for their comments.
Finally, we thank the Ross School of Business and CIBER, University of Michigan, as well as the French
National Research Agency (grant number: ANR-12-BSH1-0011-01 – ANR FRANBLE), for their support.
C2016 Wiley Periodicals, Inc.
Journal of Economics & Management Strategy, Volume26, Number 2, Summer 2017, 375–402
376 Journal of Economics & Management Strategy
regulatory credibility (Levy and Spiller,1994; Holburn and Zelner, 2010), property rights
protection (Javorcik, 2004), corruption (Cuervo-Cazuna, 2006; Javorcik and Wei, 2009),
the quality of the legal system (Laeven and Woodruff, 2007), and regulatory stability
(Henisz and Zelner, 2001; Delios and Henisz, 2003) affect the level of (often foreign)
investment. Another part of this literature has focused on how the type of investments
and the organization of firm activities—for example, ownership structures in foreign
ventures—are affected by similar factors (e.g., Oxley, 1999; Henisz, 2000; Asiedu and
Esfahani, 2001; Javorcik, 2004; Branstetter et al., 2006; Uhlenbruck et al., 2006; Chong
and Gradstein, 2011; Bloom et al., 2012; Feenstra et al., 2012).
One feature uniting the microlevel empirical literature on the effect of institutions
on economic behavior is that it has been concerned almost exclusively with high-tech and
manufacturing firms. Of course, institutional factors also affect firms in other sectors.
In fact, in some sectors, such as many retail and service industries, firms can access
customers in markets only by being present locally. Thus, contrary to what occurs in
manufacturing, firms in the retail and service sectors often must put assets at risk if they
are to do business in a country: they cannot simply locate in, and export from, countries
where both physical and intangible assets are better protected.
Among retail and service firms, lodging companies are particularly susceptible
to the types of expropriation and hold-up problems emphasized in the literature.1In
this paper, we develop a simple model to show how the existence of three modes
of organization in this industry—franchising, company ownership, and management
contracts—allows hotel firms to adjust to different local market conditions. We argue in
particular that management contracts, which combine aspects of company ownership
and franchising, give lodging firms the opportunity to protect themselves against expro-
priation risks while also protecting the value of their intangible assets, namely the value
of their brands. Wetest the predictions of the model using a unique, proprietary data set
with information on the organizational form under which all of the international hotels
affiliated with a specific major multinational, multibrand lodging company operate. A
confidentiality agreement prohibits us from disclosing the name of the company or char-
acteristics that might lead to its identification. We therefore refer to it as the Company,
and keep all references to its operations and brands oblique.
Our results imply that, consistent with evidence from the literature on high-tech
and manufacturing firms mentioned above, the Company eschews asset ownership in
markets where the quality of the institutional environment is low.However, rather than
minimizing its involvement by turning over operational control to local partners, as
would occur under franchising, the Company maintains control by relying instead on
management contracts in these environments. We interpret these findings as evidence
that in environments with lower quality institutions, the Company not only faces poten-
tial risks of expropriation, per arguments in the literature, but also major difficulties in
enforcing franchise contract terms. The latter, in turn, can lead to important free-riding
risks and potentially costly legal and other disputes under franchising, all of which
are much less severe under management contracts given the level of control that this
organizational form affords hotel firms.
We show that our results are robust to a variety of alternative specifications.
In particular, when we include separate variables designed to proxy for the risk of
1. See specific examples for hotels further below. However, these issues are not absent in other service
sectors. See James (2008) for example. Recent troubles experienced by McDonald’s in Russia provide yet
another example (see e.g., Gorst, 2014).

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT