The production economics of economics production

Date01 February 2021
AuthorBen G. Li,Yushan Hu
Published date01 February 2021
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jems.12399
J Econ Manage Strat. 2021;30:228255.wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/jems228
|
© 2020 Wiley Periodicals LLC
Received: 24 May 2018
|
Revised: 29 June 2020
|
Accepted: 23 July 2020
DOI: 10.1111/jems.12399
ORIGINAL ARTICLE
The production economics of economics production
Yushan Hu
1
|Ben G. Li
2
1
School of Economics, Renmin University
of China, Beijing, China
2
Department of Economics, University of
Massachusetts, Lowell, Massachusetts
Correspondence
Ben G. Li, Department of Economics,
University of Massachusetts, Lowell,
Massachusetts, MA 01854.
Email: benli36@gmail.com
Abstract
How is new economic knowledge produced over time? That depends on how
the expertise of authors is managed within economic journals. Using data from
41 major economics journals spanning 21 years (19942014), we find that both
the intensive margin (article length) and extensive margin (article number) of
the discipline have been growing. In particular, the extensive margin has
outgrown the intensive margin, such that each article produces absolutely
more but relatively less knowledge. This pattern is highly consistent with a
model of withinjournal specialization. As predicted by the model, the share of
an individual article shrinks less in general interest journals and in more
prestigious journals, where expertise is less substitutable across topics.
1|INTRODUCTION
Readers' willingness to pay for journals is declining. Discontinuing print journals is a current trend in university
libraries. Electronic journals are sold online, though their unit of sale is the article. This is anything but surprising.
Working papers now become freely accessible online long before being published, and many final drafts remain freely
accessible after being published. Journals are diminishing in their role as knowledge disseminators and instead are
transitioning to a role as qualitycontrolled repositories of knowledge.
1
An average page in a journal receives less
attention now than in the preinternet era when researchers relied on journals to stay on the frontier of research
advancements.
This study is concerned with how the annual outputs of journals, including their length and number of published
articles, have evolved in the new age. Our data cover 41 prestigious economic journals, spanning two decades
(19942014) that coincided with the time when the World Wide Web and online search engines revolutionized in-
dividual information intake.
2
We find that journal length, article length, and number of published articles have been
steadily increasing, and more important, the page share of an average article within a journal has been decreasing.
Think of every journal as a knowledgemaking firm that charges consumers for every page of knowledge they read,
journal length as its total output, and articles as its knowledgemaking teams. The observed data pattern suggests that
every team produces absolutely more but relatively less.
The observed data pattern is consistent with what an analogical withinfirm specialization model predicts. As
readers' attention on every published page declines, their willingness to pay reduces. In response, journals raise their
outputs to compensate for the lost revenues. Suppose that introducing a team of experts (an article) incurs a fixed cost,
and letting a few teams produce all the output overstretches their expertise. Then, as a tradeoff, every journal has an
optimal number of teams (number of articles) every year, conditional on its annual output. When journals produce
greater annual total outputs, the fixed costs of additional teams (articles) are economized. As a result, a greater number
of articles are published, each being more focused on its core expertise. Therefore, both journal length and article
number grow, with the latter margin growing more to reduce every article's output (page) share; that is, the extensive
margin outgrows the intensive margin as the amount of economic knowledge increases over time.
Up to this point, withinjournal specialization is just one possible explanation. We next derive unique predictions
from it. Within a journal's scope, if the expertise is less substitutable across topics, the fixed costs of publishing more
articles will be less economized, so that the page share of individual articles should decrease less. Conceivably,
the expertise on one topic is more discounted on other topics (a) in generalinterest journals than in field journals, and
(b) in journals with stronger expertise overall. Thus, the pageshare decrease should be less in generalinterest journals
and in better ranked journals. These hypotheses are found to be supported by the data, and our findings are robust to
the use of different estimation methods, subsamples, and journal rankings.
Apart from type and ranking, there are two other journal characteristics that relate to the substitutability of
expertise across topics within a journal. One is whether a journal imposes a page limit on initial submissions. We find
the journals with such page limits highly conforming to our earlier hypotheses, while the patterns from the journals
without page limits are weaker. This is consistent with the thesis of Card and DellaVigna (2014) on revealed preferences
in submissionsauthors shorten their submissions following the imposed page limits if they have no better outlets that
match their papers' qualities. A natural implication of their thesis is that journals would not impose page limits if the
risk of having authors extend beyond their expertise is not a significant concern. In other words, for journals that
impose page limits on initial submissions, submissions longer than the page limits overstretch the expertise that the
journals believe those submissions to have.
The other journal characteristic that relates to the substitutability of expertise across topics is the degree of spe-
cialization of the researchers. In research fields that have more specialized researchers, the crosstopic expertise loss is
expected to be less, so that the decrease in the page share of individual articles should be greater. In other words, letting
morespecialized experts author articles in their fields runs a lower risk of overstretching expertise. We use the
fieldspecific specialization index compiled by Ellison (2002a) and find evidence in support of our hypothesis.
The key mechanism of withinjournal specialization is that journals, in a highly competitive environment, push
articles to be short and focal. Dixit (1998) has an eloquent anecdote on this tendency:
As an editor of the Review of Economic Studies, (Frank) Hahn asked the author to cut down his paper from
40 pages to its essential core of three pages. When the author wrote a long and indignant letter, Hahn
responded in two sentences: Crick and Watson described the structure of DNA in three pages. Kindly explain
why your idea deserves more space.
The analogy used by Frank Hahn may not be entirely appropriate, because the writing in economics, unlike that in hard
sciences that build on lab experiments, usually needs more detailed descriptions, explanations, and justifications. Never-
theless, his analogy exemplifies a key tradeoff in the business of academic publishing: a longer article is richer but easily
strays from its central insights, and delivering more insightsinfewerpagesisthekeytopublishingasuccessfuljournal.
The first contribution of this paper is demonstrating the specialization patterns in the production of economic
knowledge. Economics is a discipline about specialization and its own evolution exemplifies specialization. Starting as
an inquiry into the nature and causes of the wealth of nations(Smith, 1776), economics has grown to be a modern
social science that has 849 clusters of research topics (defined by JEL codes) and 2,527 journals (according to RePEc
registrations).
3
The 41 economics journals covered by our 21year sample published 55,244 research articles. These
articles specialized in distinct topics, which went far beyond the nature and causes of the wealth of nations,and no
modern economist can claim that she understands all of these articles even at a superficial level. Adam Smith referred
to such a phenomenon as a division of labor.
There exist various approaches to formulating Adam Smith's division of labor. We built a variant of Chaney and
Ossa (2013) to guide our empirical study.
4
The approach taken by Chaney and Ossa (2013), featuring monopolistic
competition, introduces different teams, instead of pure labor, into the firms that make differentiated products.
Launching more teams incurs more fixed costs, but letting teams specialize in certain parts of production reduces
variable costs. This informs the importance of optimizing the structure of teams (essentially, expertise units) in the
production of any expertiseintensive product. As teams become more specialized, they each are responsible for less, but
more teams are contributing at the same time and every team is becoming more productive. Think of a research project
as a team that adds to the body of economic knowledge. We believe that most economists agree with us on the
increasing sophistication of economics papers, the narrowing breadth of research topics, and at the same time the
remarkably rapid growth of modern economic knowledge.
This paper also sheds light on the operation of the economics profession. Economists have studied the whole production
line in their own profession, from authorship (Hamermesh, 2013) and coauthorship (Laband & Tollison, 2000;Ray&
HU AND LI
|
229

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT