The Price of Political Uncertainty: Theory and Evidence from the Option Market

Published date01 October 2016
AuthorPIETRO VERONESI,BRYAN KELLY,ĽUBOŠ PÁSTOR
Date01 October 2016
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jofi.12406
THE JOURNAL OF FINANCE VOL. LXXI, NO. 5 OCTOBER 2016
The Price of Political Uncertainty: Theory and
Evidence from the Option Market
BRYAN KELLY, ˇ
LUBO ˇ
SP´
ASTOR, and PIETRO VERONESI
ABSTRACT
We empirically analyze the pricing of political uncertainty, guided by a theoretical
model of government policy choice. To isolate political uncertainty, we exploit its vari-
ation around national elections and global summits. We findthat politicaluncertainty
is priced in the equity option market as predicted by theory.Options whose lives span
political events tend to be more expensive. Such options provide valuable protection
against the price, variance, and tail risks associated with political events. This pro-
tection is more valuable in a weaker economy and amid higher political uncertainty.
The effects of political uncertainty spill over across countries.
POLITICAL UNCERTAINTY HAS FEATURED PROMINENTLY in the economic landscape
of recent years. In the United States, much uncertainty surrounded the gov-
ernment bailouts during the financial crisis of 2008, the reforms of finance
and health care, the Federal Reserve’s innovative monetary policy, tax policy,
as well as the political brinkmanship over the debt ceiling in 2011 and 2013.
Standard & Poor’s named political uncertainty as a key reason for its first-
ever downgrade of the U.S. Treasury debt in 2011. In Europe, the sovereign
debt crisis has witnessed tremendous uncertainty about the actions of Euro-
pean politicians, central bankers, and Greek voters. Alas, despite the salience
of political uncertainty, our understanding of its effects on the economy and
financial markets is only beginning to emerge.
All authors are at the University of Chicago Booth School of Business and NBER. P´
astor
and Veronesi are also at the CEPR. P´
astor is also a member of the board of the National Bank
of Slovakia. The views in this paper are those of the authors, not of the institutions they are
affiliated with. We are grateful for comments from participants at the 2015 AFA meetings, 2015
NBER Summer Institute, 2015 NYU/Penn Conference on Law and Finance, 2015 Queen Mary
Conference on Recent Advances in Finance, 2014 Asset Pricing Retreat at Tilburg, 2014 Duke/UNC
Asset Pricing Conference, 2014 EFAmeetings, 2014 ESSFM Gerzensee, 2014 Princeton conference
on “The Causes and Consequences of Policy Uncertainty,” 2015 FARFE conference, 2014 Rising
Stars Conference, 2014 SoFiE Conference, and seminars at Bocconi, Chicago, EDHEC, Imperial,
Pennsylvania, Rochester, UCLA, Wisconsin, and the National Bank of Slovakia. We also thank
Jonathan Brogaard, Andrea Buraschi, Hui Chen, John Cochrane, George Constantinides, Ian Dew-
Becker, Michael Gofman, Brandon Julio, Juhani Linnainmaa, Rajnish Mehra, Toby Moskowitz,
Stavros Panageas, Jay Shanken, Ken Singleton, Raghu Sundaram, Eric Talley, Moto Yogo, and
two anonymous referees. Gerardo Manzo and Sarah Kervin provided excellent research assistance.
This research was funded in part by the Fama-Miller Center for Research in Finance and by the
Center for Research in Security Prices at the University of Chicago Booth School of Business.
DOI: 10.1111/jofi.12406
2417
2418 The Journal of Finance R
Recent research suggests that uncertainty about government actions has
negative real and financial effects. For example, Baker,Bloom, and Davis (2013)
find that this uncertainty,as measured by their index, increases unemployment
and reduces investment. Using the same index, P´
astor and Veronesi (2013)
find that this uncertainty commands a risk premium, and that stocks are
more volatile and more correlated in times of high uncertainty. Fern´
andez-
Villaverde et al. (2012) find that uncertainty about fiscal policy, as measured
by time-varying volatility of tax and spending processes, has negative effects
on economic activity.
A key obstacle in assessing the impact of political uncertainty is the difficulty
in isolating exogenous variation in this uncertainty.Political uncertainty likely
depends on a host of factors, such as macroeconomic uncertainty. The time-
series measures of Baker, Bloom, and Davis (2013) and Fern´
andez-Villaverde
et al. (2012) might potentially reflect not only government-related uncertainty
but also broader uncertainty about economic fundamentals.
In this paper, we isolate political uncertainty by exploiting its variation
around major political events, namely, national elections and global summits.
We investigate whether and how the uncertainty associated with these events
is priced in the option market. Options are uniquely well suited for this analy-
sis, for two reasons. First, they have relatively short maturities, which we can
choose to cover the dates of political events. An option whose life spans a politi-
cal event provides protection against the risk associated with that event. Since
the political event is often the main event that occurs during the option’s short
life, the option’s price is informative about the value of protection against po-
litical risk. Second, options come with different strike prices, which allow us to
examine various types of risk associated with political events, such as tail risk.
Elections and summits are also well suited for our analysis because they can
result in major policy shifts. Moreover, the dates of elections and summits are
determined sufficiently far in advance so that they are publicly known on the
dates at which we calculate the prices of the options spanning the events. These
events thus provide a source of exogenous variation in political uncertainty.
Our analysis is guided by the theoretical model of P´
astor and Veronesi (2013,
hereafter PV). In this model, the government decides which policy to adopt
and investors are uncertain about the future policy choice. We use this model
directly when analyzing global summits. When we analyze national elections,
we reinterpret the PV model so that voters decide whom to elect and investors
face uncertainty about the election outcome. Under the election interpretation,
political uncertainty is uncertainty about who will be elected; in the original
version of the model, it is uncertainty about which government policy will be
chosen.1
1Both interpretations of political uncertainty are mentioned in the following recent quote:
“When economists talk of political risk, they usually mean...national elections...But there is another
kind of political risk: the temptation for governments of all political colours to change the rules,
whether they relate to tax, the way that companies operate or how markets behave. And that risk
has increased significantly since the 2008 crisis” (The Economist, Buttonwood, November 9, 2013).
The Price of Political Uncertainty 2419
We derive the option pricing implications of the PV model, obtaining a closed-
form solution for the prices of put options whose lives span a political event.
We calculate three option market variables: the implied volatility of an at-
the-money (ATM) option, the slope of the function relating implied volatility
to moneyness, and the variance risk premium. These variables capture the
value of option protection against three aspects of risk associated with political
events: price risk, tail risk, and variance risk, respectively. In response to a
political event, stock prices might drop (price risk), the price drop might be
large (tail risk), and return volatility might rise (variance risk). These risks
are correlated inside the PV model; for example, the adoption of a risky policy
can raise volatility while depressing stock prices. The model implies that all
three option market variables should be larger, on average, than the same
variables calculated for options whose lives do not span a political event.
The model also predicts a negative relation between all three option market
variables and economic conditions. This prediction follows from a key result
in the PV model: when the economy is weaker, the current government policy
is less likely to be retained, creating uncertainty about which new policy will
be adopted instead. Similarly, in the election version of the model, the incum-
bent government is less likely to be reelected in a weaker economy, creating
uncertainty about the new government. Options provide protection against an
unfavorable policy decision or an undesirable election outcome. Since the prob-
ability of such an outcome is higher in a weaker economy, so is the value of the
option protection.
Finally, the model predicts that all three option market variables should be
larger amid higher political uncertainty.When there is no such uncertainty, op-
tion prices are governed by the Black-Scholes formula, so that implied volatility
equals expected volatility and both the implied volatility slope and the variance
risk premium are zero. When the uncertainty is present, the option protection
against all three aspects of political risk is valuable.
In our empirical analysis, we test the model’s predictions on option data
from 20 countries. We analyze two types of political events: national elections
and global summits. Each summit counts as a separate event for all countries
participating in the summit, while elections count only for the country in which
they are held. For each political event, we calculate the three option market
variables based on options whose lives span the event, adjusting each variable
for its mean calculated for neighboring options whose lives do not span the
event.
We find strong empirical support for the model’s predictions. First, the un-
conditional means of all three variables are significantly positive, for both elec-
tions and summits. The average (mean-adjusted) implied volatility is 1.43%
per year, which implies that one-month ATM put options whose lives span
political events tend to be 5.1% more expensive than neighboring options.2
2The 5.1% price premium is economically large. For example, if one were to purchase enough
one-month ATM put options to insure the total market value of the S&P 500 index in March 2014,
the additional cost for options that span political events would be over $15 billion. To obtain this

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT