The Marketisation of Early Childhood Education and Care (ECEC) in Australia: A Structured Response

DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/faam.12018
AuthorDeborah Brennan,Susan Newberry
Published date01 August 2013
Date01 August 2013
Financial Accountability & Management, 29(3), August 2013, 0267-4424
The Marketisation of Early
Childhood Education and Care
(ECEC) in Australia: A Structured
Response
SUSAN NEWBERRY AND DEBORAH BRENNAN
Abstract: The marketisation of early childhood education and care (ECEC) offers
opportunities to test assumptions about the benefits of a market framework.
In Australia, where marketisation included reshaping, extending, and increasing
government subsidies, one major listed company (ABC Learning Limited) emerged to
dominate child care. Child care prices increased rapidly to become an election issue,
and government subsidies increased. ABC acknowledged its economic dependence
on government policy and subsidies. Until its collapse in 2008, ABC was the world’s
largest listed child care operator, and operating internationally. ABC’s structured
business model separated child care properties (propco) from child care operations
(opco). ABC was the opco and leased the child care properties from propcos. As
ABC grew and replicated its structured model to other forms of property including
intangible assets, the rising child care prices and government subsidies supported
a growing array of other enterprises all seeking profitable operations. This paper
explains the structured opco-propco model, identifies its interaction with accounting
and lessons to be learned from marketisation.
Keywords: marketisation, child care, opco-propco, PPP, government subsidies
INTRODUCTION
During the last 30 years of economic restructuring and new public management
style (NPM) public sector reforms, governments internationally have been
urged to reduce their size and role (see, for example, World Bank, 1995).
Regulations to support competitive markets have been a feature of the economic
restructuring, and various forms of privatisation a feature of public sector
The authors are respectively, Professor of Accounting, University of Sydney Business School;
and Professor, Social Policy Research Centre, The University of New South Wales.
Address for correspondence: Susan Newberry, Professor of Accounting, University of Sydney
Business School, The University of Sydney, NSW 2006, Australia.
e-mail: Susan.Newberry@sydney.edu.au
C
2013 John Wiley & Sons Ltd, 9600 Garsington Road,
Oxford OX4 2DQ, UK and 350 Main Street, Malden, MA 02148, USA. 227
228 NEWBERRY AND BRENNAN
reforms. These include outright privatisation by disposal of state assets and/or
state-run operations, and reducing the government’s role and activities in favour
of market arrangements (Osborne and Plaistrik, 1997; and Salamon, 2002).
Competition and privatisation are thus complementary features of reform, with
increasing private provision counter-balancing shrinking government provision.
Trade liberalisation negotiations that encompass services coincided with these
changes. Various social services, including education and health services, that
in many countries have been provided by governments or controlled for social
reasons are today candidates for trade liberalisation (Kelsey, 2008). Gradually,
these services are being reshaped into market-like activities. The underlying
assumption is that all services should be open to private provision in market
conditions. Political sensitivity, especially about social services, means that
ideological preferences for market arrangements may be de-emphasised and
potential benefits emphasised (Savas, 2000; and Feigenbaum et al., 1998).
Competitive markets are supposed to improve cost effectiveness and increase
choice of services (Savas, 2000, pp. 119–20).
This paper addresses the radical marketisation of one social service, early
childhood education and care (ECEC) that, in Australia, was not a government-
provided service. Rather, it was provided in the private sector by a mix of small
private providers and government-subsidised small community organisations.1
Australia’s generic National Competition Policy (NCP) applies to the provider
side of the ECEC market, while on the purchaser side government subsidies
offset parents’ costs. Thus multiple purchasers (parents) were supposed to
purchase their choice of child care services from this child care market.
In 2001, a listed company, ABC Learning Ltd (ABC) emerged and grew
rapidly to dominate the child care sector. Child care prices spiraled, government
subsidies for parents became a regular election issue, and government funding
of parents’ child care costs grew. Before ABC collapsed in 2008, it was
the world’s largest listed child care company, with operations in the United
Kingdom, United States, Canada and New Zealand as well as Australia. ABC
was the operating arm of a structured business model called an ‘opco-propco’
(O’Connor, 2011). Under this model, property companies (propco) held the
property required to provide the service (in this case child care) and leased it
to the operating company (opco) (in this case ABC). ABC replicated the opco-
propco business model as it grew, extending it to other property and aspects of
child care. When ABC collapsed, the Commonwealth Government spent $100
million to keep the child care centres open during an orderly disposal, avoiding
the disruption to families of sudden closure.
This Australian experience is of international interest. ABC’s international
expansion meant that it received government subsidies in other countries
besides Australia and the opco-propco model has emerged elsewhere – in the
UK, for example, where there was concern about private operators’ ability
to meet growing demand for residential aged care (Lapsley and Llewellyn,
1992). The financial difficulties of a similarly structured major residential care
C
2013 John Wiley & Sons Ltd

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT