The Insurance Is the Lemon: Failing to Index Contracts

Date01 February 2020
AuthorBENJAMIN HÉBERT,BARNEY HARTMAN‐GLASER
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jofi.12856
Published date01 February 2020
THE JOURNAL OF FINANCE VOL. LXXV, NO. 1 FEBRUARY 2020
The Insurance Is the Lemon: Failing to
Index Contracts
BARNEY HARTMAN-GLASER and BENJAMIN H ´
EBERT
ABSTRACT
We model the widespread failure of contracts to share risk using available indices.
A borrower and lender can share risk by conditioning repayments on an index. The
lender has private information about the ability of this index to measure the true state
that the borrower would like to hedge. The lender is risk-averse and thus requires a
premium to insure the borrower. The borrower,however, might be paying something
for nothing if the index is a poor measure of the true state. We provide sufficient
conditions for this effect to cause the borrower to choose a nonindexed contract instead.
ACENTRAL IMPLICATION OF THE LITERATURE on financial contracting is that agents
should structure contracts to share risk as efficiently as possible. In many fi-
nancial markets, standard contracts are simple and do not include risk-sharing
arrangements that condition payments on publicly available indices. A leading
example of this phenomenon is the mortgage market. In this market, home-
owners are exposed to the risk that their homes will decline in value. Lenders
are arguably better equipped to bear this risk and could insulate homeowners
against declines in house prices by making mortgage repayment terms con-
tingent on a house-price index. These types of mortgage contracts have been
widely proposed as a solution to problems facing the mortgage market, such as
the subprime default crises of 2007,1but have failed to supplant the standard
Barney Hartman-Glaser is at the Anderson School of Management, University of California,
Los Angeles. Benjamin H´
ebert is with the Graduate School of Business, Stanford University and
the National Bureau of Economic Research. The authors would like to thank Vladimir Asriyan;
Francesca Carapella; Eduardo Davila; Peter DeMarzo; Emmanuel Farhi; Valentin Haddad; David
Hirschleifer; Christopher Hrdlicka; Roger Myerson; Batchimeg Sambalaibat; Jesse Shapiro; Alp
Simsek; Amir Sufi; David Sraer; Sebastian Di Tella; Victoria Vanasco; Jeff Zwiebel; and seminar
and conference participants at Stanford University, UC Berkeley Haas, the University of Wash-
ington Foster, the Federal Reserve Board, the Finance Theory Group Meeting at the University of
Minnesota, Columbia Law School, the Adam Smith Conference, and the 2018 WFA Meetings. We
would particularly like to thank John Kuong and Giorgia Piacentino (discussants), Philip Bond
(Editor), an anonymous associate editor, and two anonymous referees for comments that helped
improved the paper. All remaining errors are our own. We have read The Journal of Finance
disclosure policy and have no conflicts of interest to disclose.
1See, for example, the “Shared Responsibility Mortgage” proposed by Mian and Sufi (2015),
in which interest and principal payments are contingent upon local house price indices, or the
“Shared-Equity Mortgage” proposed by Caplin et al. (2007), in which a borrower receives a second
mortgage where payment is due only upon the sale of the house and is contingent on house value.
DOI: 10.1111/jofi.12856
C2019 the American Finance Association
463
464 The Journal of Finance R
mortgage. Two common explanations for this type of market failure are that
the space of feasible contracts is incomplete (Hart and Moore (1988)) or the
transaction costs associated with implementing risk-sharing contracts entails
are high transaction. Neither of these explanations applies, however, when in-
dices are available that would allow agents to share risk efficiently and that
are almost costless to contract upon.
In this paper, we develop a model in which the failure to condition on indices
and thus efficiently share risk is an equilibrium outcome resulting from asym-
metric information. In our model, an agent, who we call the borrower, seeks
financing from a set of lenders. This financial contract must be written in view
of potential conflicts of interest between the lender and the borrower, which are
related to an “internal,” or idiosyncratic, state. For example, this internal state
could represent the hidden ability of a mortgage borrower to make payments
to the lender. At the same time, there may be some benefits of risk-sharing be-
tween the lender and the borrower over some imperfectly measured state (e.g.,
local area house prices). We refer to this state as “external” to indicate that
it is unaffected by the actions of the lenders and the borrower. The external
state is not directly observable. To realize any risk-sharing benefits, the con-
tracts must condition on some potentially imperfect measurement of the state,
which we call an index (e.g., a house price index). Lenders know the true joint
distribution of the index and the external state (i.e., the quality of the index),
while the borrower does not. In effect, the borrower faces an adverse selection
problem over basis risk when lenders offer an indexed contract.
At least two equilibria can arise in the model. In the first type of equilib-
rium, which we refer to as the full-information optimal contracts equilibrium,
all lenders offer a contract featuring the optimal amount of insurance condi-
tional on the true quality of the index. The full-information optimal contracts
equilibrium exists when there is competition between lenders and features no
loss in efficiency due to asymmetric information about the index. In the second
type of equilibrium, which we refer to as the noncontingent contracts equilib-
rium, all lenders offer a contract that does not condition on the index. To see
why such an equilibrium can arise, consider the borrower’s response when a
single lender deviates and offers a contingent contract. To at least break even
on such a contract, the lender must charge the borrower an insurance premium.
At the same time, the borrower may be concerned that the index is in fact un-
correlated with the risk that she is aiming to insure, that is, that the basis risk
for the contract is too high to justify the premium. Lenders who know the basis
risk is high are happy to offer insurance and charge a high premium because
the insurance is cheap for them to provide (precisely because the basis risk
is high). As a result, the borrower will reject the indexed contract in favor of
a standard noncontingent contract. We note that the noncontingent contracts
equilibrium exists even though the contracting space allows for the use of an
index, there are no transactions costs, and lenders make competing offers.
To illustrate the intuition behind these two equilibria, suppose that there
are two equally likely external states, “good” and “bad.” Now suppose that
a borrower receives offers of one dollar of financing from several competing
The Insurance is the Lemon 465
lenders. The borrower is risk-averse with respect to the external state, meaning
that her expected marginal value of a dollar is 1/2 in the good state and 3/2in
the bad state. The lenders are also risk-averse, but less so than the borrower.
Their expected marginal value of a dollar is 3/4 in the good state and 5/4in
the bad state. Lenders can offer contracts that are contingent upon some index
but not upon the true external state directly. The index can be “high quality,”
in which case it is perfectly correlated with the true underlying state, or “low
quality,” in which case it is independent of the true state and hence unrelated
to the either the borrower’s or the lender’s preferences. The borrower believes
that these two cases are equally likely but lenders observe the quality of the
index before making their offers. Finally, the lenders cannot offer contracts
that specify positive transfers from the lender to the borrower.
Suppose that the lenders make the following offers, depending on the quality
of the index. If the index is of high quality,they offer a contract that calls for the
borrower to repay 8/3 dollars if the realization of the index indicates the good
state and nothing otherwise. If the index is of low quality, they offer a contract
that calls for the borrower to repay one dollar regardless of the realization
of the index. These offers constitute what we call a full-information optimal
contracts equilibrium. To see why they can arise in equilibrium, note that all
lenders earn weakly positive profits and could not possibly earn more by making
different offers. Moreover, given that all lenders have common information, the
borrower can perfectly infer the quality of the index by observing the contracts
that the lenders offer. In other words, it is not possible for a single lender
to convince the borrower that the index is of high quality if all of the other
lenders offer a noncontingent contract. This same intuition carries over to the
second type of equilibrium we describe, that is, the noncontingent contracts
equilibrium.
Now suppose that all lenders offer a contract that calls for the borrower to
repay one dollar regardless of whether the index is of high or low quality.These
offers constitute what we call the noncontingent contracts equilibrium. Can
a single lender gain by deviating and offering the best contingent contract?
Again, the answer is no. If a single lender deviates by offering a contingent
contract, then she will have to charge a premium for it to at least break even,
where by premium, we mean that the contract calls for the borrower to repay
an amount that in expectation exceeds the amount financed. In the case of the
best contingent contract, the expected repayment of the borrower is 4/3, that
is, 8/3 (the repayment if the index is in a good state) times 1/2 (the probability
that the index is in a good state), while the amount financed is one, so that
the premium is 1/3. If the index is of low quality, lenders are risk-neutral with
respect to the index and the premium is pure profit. If the index is of high
quality, the premium is compensation for risk and leaves the lenders with zero
net present value. Consequently, a lender would be at least as willing to make
this offer given a low-quality index as when given a high-quality index. As such,
standard belief refinements imply that the borrower can believe that the index
is low quality after observing this deviation. Given these beliefs, the borrower is
strictly better off when accepting one of the offers of a noncontingent contract.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT