The Impact of Venture Capital Monitoring

DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jofi.12370
Date01 August 2016
AuthorRICHARD R. TOWNSEND,XAVIER GIROUD,SHAI BERNSTEIN
Published date01 August 2016
THE JOURNAL OF FINANCE VOL. LXXI, NO. 4 AUGUST 2016
The Impact of Venture Capital Monitoring
SHAI BERNSTEIN, XAVIER GIROUD, and RICHARD R. TOWNSEND
ABSTRACT
We show that venture capitalists’ (VCs) on-site involvement with their portfolio com-
panies leads to an increase in both innovation and the likelihood of a successful exit.
We rule out selection effects by exploiting an exogenous source of variation in VC
involvement: the introduction of new airline routes that reduce VCs’ travel times to
their existing portfolio companies. We confirm the importance of this channel by con-
ducting a large-scale survey of VCs, of whom almost 90% indicate that direct flights
increase their interaction with their portfolio companies and management, and help
them better understand companies’ activities.
IT IS OFTEN ARGUED that venture capital (VC) plays an important role in promot-
ing innovation and growth. Consistent with this belief, governments around the
world have pursued a number of policies aimed at fostering VC activity (Lerner
(2009)). However, evidence that the activities of VCs actually play a causal role
in stimulating the creation of innovative and successful companies is scarce.
It could be the case, for instance, that VCs simply select companies that are
poised to innovate and succeed, even absent their involvement. In this paper,
we examine whether the activities of VCs do affect portfolio company outcomes.
An ideal experiment to establish the impact of VCs would be to randomly
provide certain companies with VC funding and others not. Such an experi-
ment would eliminate the selection of companies (“screening”), thus allowing
us to estimate the effect of VC involvement (“monitoring”).1Unfortunately, it
Shai Bernstein is with Stanford University, Graduate School of Business. Xavier Giroud is
with the MIT Sloan School of Management, NBER, and CEPR. Richard Townsend is with the
Tuck School of Business at Dartmouth College. We are grateful to Michael Roberts (the Edi-
tor), two anonymous referees, Bo Becker, Jos´
e-Miguel Gaspar, Yael Hochberg, Dirk Jenter, Anna
Kovner, Josh Lerner, Laura Lindsey, Holger Mueller, Francisco P´
erez-Gonz´
alez, David Robinson,
Antoinette Schoar, Rob Seamans, Scott Stern, as well as seminar participants at Columbia (GSB),
Dartmouth (Tuck), Duisenberg School of Finance and Tinbergen Institute, EFA (Lugano), EPFL
and University of Lausanne, Economics of Entrepreneurship and Innovation Conference (Queen’s),
HKUST,Harvard (HBS), LBS Private Equity Findings Symposium, MIT (Sloan), MIT Micro@Sloan
Conference, NBER Entrepreneurship Meetings, Nanyang TechnologicalUniversity, Northeastern,
Northwestern (Kellogg), Norwegian School of Economics, SFS Finance Cavalcade (Georgetown),
Singapore Management University,Stanford (GSB), UCSD (Rady), UNC (Kenan-Flagler), Univer-
sity of Bergen, University of Illinois at Chicago, University of Maryland (Smith), and University
of Miami School of Business for helpful comments and suggestions. The authors declare that they
have no relevant or material financial interests related to the research in this paper.
1Kaplan and Str¨
omberg (2001) review the screening and monitoring roles of VCs and emphasize
the difficulty of disentangling them.
DOI: 10.1111/jofi.12370
1591
1592 The Journal of Finance R
is quite difficult to identify a setting that convincingly approximates this ex-
periment. That being said, another useful experiment would be to randomly
vary VC involvement after initial investments are made. This would allow us to
identify the effect of VC involvement, holding company selection fixed. In par-
ticular, if differences in outcomes for VC-backed companies are driven purely
by selection, postinvestment involvement of VCs should have no effect. In this
paper, we attempt to approximate this second experiment.
The source of exogenous variation in VC involvement that we exploit is
the introduction of new airline routes that reduce the travel time between
VC firms and their existing portfolio companies. Previous work suggests that
travel time reductions lower monitoring costs for firms with headquarters that
are geographically separated from their production facilities (Giroud (2013)). If
VC activities matter, reductions in the cost of monitoring should translate into
better portfolio company performance by facilitating VC’s ability to engage in
these activities.
To obtain direct evidence on whether VC involvement increases following
reductions in travel time, we conduct a large-scale survey of VC investors. Al-
most 90% of the 306 survey participants agreed that they would visit a portfolio
company more frequently following the introduction of a direct flight. Survey
participants also agreed that the introduction of a direct flight would help them
establish better relationships with management teams, improve their under-
standing of the state of their companies, and generally add more value. This
qualitative evidence supports our underlying assumption that VC involvement
is responsive to the introduction of direct flights, and is consistent with aca-
demic literature showing VC activity is sensitive to geographic proximity.2
We next explore how the introduction of new airline routes that reduce the
travel time between VCs and their portfolio companies affects company-level
outcomes. The primary outcomes we examine are the quantity and quality of
innovation (as measured by patent count and citations per patent, respectively),
as well as success (as measured by exit via initial public offering (IPO) or
acquisition). Using a difference-in-differences estimation framework, we find
that the introduction of a new airline route leads to a 3.1% increase in the
number of patents the portfolio company produces and a 5.8% increase in
the number of citations per patent it receives. Furthermore, the treatment
increases the probability of going public by 1.0% and the probability of having
a successful exit (via IPO or acquisition) by 1.4%. These results indicate that
VC involvement is an important determinant of innovation and success.
A natural concern is that local shocks, in the region of either the VC or the
portfolio company, could be driving the results. For example, a booming local
economy may lead to both increased innovation and the introduction of a new
airline route. In this case, we may estimate a spurious positive effect of travel
time reductions on innovation. However, since our treatment is defined at the
2For example, Lerner (1995) finds that VCs are more likely to sit on boards of geographically
proximate companies. Chen et al. (2010) further find that VCs are more likely to invest in a distant
region if they already visit one portfolio company in the region.
The Impact of Venture Capital Monitoring 1593
VC-portfolio company level, we can control for such local shocks. Specifically,we
include Metropolitan Statistical Area (MSA) by year fixed effects for the MSAs
of both the VC and the portfolio company. Moreover, we find that pre-existing
trends are not driving our results, and the results are robust to considering only
new airline routes that are the outcome of a merger between two airlines or the
opening of a new hub. Such treatments are likely to be even more exogenous
to any given VC-portfolio company pair.
We provide further evidence on the underlying channel through which these
effects operate by taking advantage of the fact that certain VCs should be
more sensitive to changes in monitoring costs than others. VCs often syndicate
their investments. When this occurs, one typically takes the role of the lead
investor.The lead investor is generally more actively involved in the monitoring
of the portfolio company, while others act more as passive providers of capital
(Gorman and Sahlman (1989)). Given that lead VCs play a greater role in
monitoring, their monitoring effort should be more sensitive to reductions in
monitoring costs, as should portfolio company performance. We find that our
results are indeed driven primarily by reductions in travel time for lead VCs
rather than other members of the investment syndicate.
Our paper contributes to a growing literature that studies the effect of VCs
on portfolio company outcomes. Much of this literature tries to disentangle VC
monitoring from screening by comparing outcomes of VC-backed and non-VC-
backed companies (e.g., Hellmann and Puri (2002), Chemmanur,Krishnan, and
Nandy (2011), Puri and Zarutskie (2012)). These papers are valuable given the
scarcity of data on young companies that are not affiliated with a VC. However,
even if both groups of companies are matched on the basis of observables,
it is possible that VCs select companies with higher potential ex ante—an
inherently unobservable characteristic. In contrast, our setting allows us to
identify the effect of VC monitoring while holding selection fixed, as we exploit
exogenous reductions in monitoring costs after initial investments are made.
Other papers rely on structural modeling. In particular,Sorensen (2007) models
the two-sided matching of VCs and entrepreneurs to structurally estimate the
relative importance of VC monitoring and screening as explanations for why
companies backed by more experienced VCs outperform. Similarly,Kortum and
Lerner (2000) structurally estimate industry-level patent production functions
with corporate R&D and VC as inputs to compare their relative potency. Our
paper differs from these studies in that it does not require any structural
assumptions for identification.
Our paper also contributes to a large, mostly theoretical literature that ex-
plores how financial contracts shape the interaction between entrepreneurs
and VC firms, alleviating moral hazard and agency problems. For example,
several papers consider the optimal contractual arrangement that leads both
entrepreneurs and VCs to contribute effort to promote a venture’s success in a
double moral hazard setting (e.g., Schmidt (2003), Casamatta (2003), Inderst
and Mueller (2004), Hellmann (2006)). Other theoretical work highlights the
importance of contractual arrangements on the VC refinancing versus termi-
nation decision (e.g., Cornelli and Yosha (2003), Repullo and Suarez (2004),

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT