The impact of job training on temporary worker performance: Field experimental evidence from insurance sales agents

AuthorElizabeth Lyons
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jems.12333
Date01 January 2020
Published date01 January 2020
J Econ Manage Strat. 2020;29:122146.wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/jems122
|
© 2019 Wiley Periodicals, Inc.
Received: 20 June 2018
|
Revised: 17 September 2019
|
Accepted: 2 October 2019
DOI: 10.1111/jems.12333
INVITED REVIEW
The impact of job training on temporary worker
performance: Field experimental evidence from insurance
sales agents
Elizabeth Lyons
School of Global Policy and Strategy,
University of California, La Jolla, San
Diego, California
Correspondence
Elizabeth Lyons, School of Global Policy
and Strategy, University of California,
9500 Gilman Drive, MC 0519 La Jolla, San
Diego, CA 920930519.
Email: lizlyons@ucsd.edu
Funding information
Center on Global Transformation,
University of California, San Diego; The
Center on Global Transformation and the
Policy Design and Evaluation Lab at UC
San Diego
Abstract
Despite the limited incentives they provide for idiosyncratic investment,
temporary work arrangements are becoming increasingly common. Using
evidence from a field experiment conducted among salespeople in a Kenyan
insurance firm, this paper examines the consequences of providing job training
for temporary workers. The findings show that providing access to training
significantly increases firm revenue, primarily due to performance increases
among higherability workers. The findings from the study are consistent with
temporary workers willingness to invest in job training when the jobspecific
returns from doing so are sufficiently high.
KEYWORDS
contract workers, field experiment, training
JEL CLASSIFICATION
J24; J49; M53; O33
1
|
INTRODUCTION
Shortterm work arrangements have increased drastically over the past two decades. For instance, alternative work
arrangements
1
accounted for 15.8% of employment contracts in the US in 2015, up from 10.1% in 2005 (Katz & Krueger,
2019).
2
Importantly, this type of employment is not restricted to routine tasks for which the required skills and
knowledge are relatively standardized across employers. Many complex jobs that were previously performed inhouse
are being contracted out.
3
These changes are driven in part by advances in information and communications
technology (ICT; Agrawal, Horton, Lacetera, & Lyons, 2015), and by labor market shifts following the Great Recession
(Brainard, 2016).
Although the current discussion surrounding the rise of nonstandard work arrangements sometimes suggests that
the growth in temporary work is boundless,
4
an important barrier to this growth, particularly in nonroutine jobs, may
be the importance of job training for ensuring satisfactory worker performance. Employer provided incentives and
opportunities to acquire knowledge is more limited for temporary workers than for permanent employees (e.g., Becker,
1962; Lazear, 2009).
5
Understanding the extent to which providing temporary workers with lowcost opportunities to
invest in job training affects firm performance is critical for firm management of these work arrangements, and for
understanding the development of the contract labor market and the ondemand economy more generally.
This paper contributes to a better understanding of the performance implications of job training among temporary
workers, and how this varies with their shortrun incentives to invest in this training. I present evidence from a field
experiment that randomly assigns job training access to salespeople employed for a 2month sales window by an
insurance firm in Kenya. Specifically, the experiment tests whether giving these workers the option to invest in job
training affects their performance, and how this varies with financial incentives from the current job to invest in the
training. To overcome difficulties associated with causally linking human capital investment to performance outcomes
(Card, 1999), the performance of insurance sales agents who were randomly assigned a job training mobile application
is compared with the performance of a control population who did not receive the application. Direct incentives for
training investment were randomly assigned among those given access to the job training application.
The population of workers in this study was hired for a 2month period to perform outside sales of insurance for
droughtrelated livestock losses, and paid commission for their sales. Turnover among these agents is quite high;
between the sales window before the experiment and period of the experiment, only 38% of the sales agents were
retained. The sales agency model under which they work is similar to the sales agency model employed by many
American organizations, including insurance firms (e.g., Regan & Tennyson, 1996). It is also a distribution model that is
frequently employed in SubSaharan Africa to overcome difficulties associated with infrastructure development and
human capital shortages that firms face when trying to serve rural markets (Dihel, 2011). Importantly, these sales
agents have a complex task that requires both general sales and accounting skills, and specific knowledge about the
insurance product they are selling.
Findings from my experiment demonstrate a positive impact of providing temporary workers access to job training
on firm revenue. Mean comparisons show that sales agents in my sample who were given access to job training had
approximately nine times the total sales of those who were not; approximately 40,000 KSH relative to 5,000 KSH in the
control.
6
However, there is substantial heterogeneity in the effects of providing job training across worker types.
Consistent with the benefits of offering training differing by trainees shortterm incentives for investing in it, I find
that providing the option to invest in job training improves firm outcomes by improving the performance of sales agents
who are most likely to benefit from the training in terms of higher earnings in their current jobs; specifically, higher
ability sales agents. Access to job training also increased the job tenure among these higherability workers. Direct
incentives to invest in training (inputbased incentives) do not alter the performance effects of training provision among
these workers with relatively high outputbased incentives to invest in training. However, I find evidence that providing
financial inputbased incentives for job training has a positive impact on the performance of agents with lower ability.
Combined, the results from this study provide support for existing theories about the conditions under which job
training will receive investment (e.g., Becker, 1962; A. Booth & Chatterji, 1989; Carmichael, 1983; Jovanovic, 1979).
They also add nuance to these theories by demonstrating the specific importance of shortterm financial incentives for
investment in job training when longerterm incentives are not present. Temporary workers are trading off the time
costs of investing in job training with the financial benefits it will generate for them in the current position and any
wage benefits it will generate in subsequent employment. Because temporary workers do not have the longerrun job
specific incentives that fulltime employees do, if the general human capital returns from job training investment are
low, financial returns need to accrue quickly in order for them to invest in it. Alternatively, in the absence of financial
benefits in the current job, the general human capital gains that job training offers need to be sufficiently large to justify
the currentperiod cost of investing in it. To my knowledge, this paper is the first to provide causal empirical evidence
on the effects of job training provision on worker performance. Moreover, this study has implications for the literature
on incentives for human capital investment more generally by demonstrating that the effectiveness of inputbased
incentives for investment in training may depend on individual expectations about the outputbased returns from
investment.
The results from this study also have practical implications for the management of temporary and contingent
workers. First, they point to the importance of ensuring these workers have relatively easy access to job training. Given
that temporary workers do not expect promotions or fear being fired as permanent employees do, incentives for
investment in jobspecific human capital may be limited and, thus, the costs of this investment to workers may need to
be lower than for permanent employees.
7
Although job training almost certainly involves knowledge transfer that is not
jobspecific, my findings suggest that workers in this study do not interpret the training they were given as having
meaningful benefits for their returns from subsequent employers. Employers who cannot effectively use outputbased
pay contracts may be able to encourage job training investments among temporary workers by providing training that
will more obviously benefit these workers in their future jobs. Alternatively, my finding that inputbased pay for job
training investment may compensate for a lack of outputbased pay suggests that employers can employ direct
incentives for job training as a partial substitute for outputbased pay. More generally, my findings suggest that if the
need for investment in job training is properly managed it may not severely hinder the growth in temporary
employment. In addition, the success of appbased job training in my research setting suggests that because ICT
LYONS
|
123

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT