The Globalization Risk Premium

AuthorJULIEN SAUVAGNAT,ERIK LOUALICHE,JEAN‐NOËL BARROT
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jofi.12780
Published date01 October 2019
Date01 October 2019
THE JOURNAL OF FINANCE VOL. LXXIV, NO. 5 OCTOBER 2019
The Globalization Risk Premium
JEAN-NO ¨
EL BARROT, ERIK LOUALICHE, and JULIEN SAUVAGNAT
ABSTRACT
In this paper, we investigate how globalization is reflected in asset prices. We use
shipping costs to measure firms’ exposure to globalization. Firms in low shipping cost
industries carry a 7% risk premium, suggesting that their cash flows covary negatively
with investors’ marginal utility. We find that the premium emanates from the risk of
displacement of least efficient firms triggered by import competition. These findings
suggest that foreign productivity shocks are associated with times when consumption
is dear for investors. We discuss conditions under which a standard model of trade
with asset prices can rationalize this puzzle.
RECENT DECADES HAVEBEEN CHARACTERIZED by a high degree of trade integration.
This era of globalization1is generally seen in a positive light, as it has been
associated with more product variety at lower prices, cheaper intermediate
goods, and greater access for U.S. firms to foreign markets.2Yet globalization
also makes domestic economies more sensitive to foreign shocks. A salient
Jean-No¨
el Barrot is with HEC Paris and CEPR. Erik Loualiche is with the University of Min-
nesota, Carlson School of Management. Julien Sauvagnat is with Bocconi University and CEPR.
For helpful comments, the authors thank Stefan Nagel (the Editor); Nick Bloom; Maria Cecilia
Bustamante (discussant); Bernard Dumas (discussant); Nicola Gennaioli; Matthieu Gomez; Pierre-
Olivier Gourinchas; Tarek Hassan (discussant); Christian Julliard; Matteo Maggiori (discussant);
Jonathan Parker; Carolin Pflueger; Thomas Philippon; Nick Roussanov (discussant); Chris Telmer
(discussant); Adrien Verdelhan; Michael Weber (discussant); anonymous referees; and seminar
participants at MIT Sloan, SED annual meetings 2015, 2015 China International Conference in Fi-
nance, 2015 European Economic Association annual meetings, 2016 ASSA meetings, Spring 2016
NBER International Trade and Investment meeting, Spring 2016 NBER International Finance
and Macroeconomics meeting, 2016 NYU Stern Macrofinance conference, 2016 Duke–UNC Asset
Pricing Conference, Spring 2016 Macro-Finance Society Meeting, CEPR First Annual Spring Sym-
posium in Financial Economics, CEPR European Symposium in International Macroeconomics,
CSEF-IGIER Symposium on Economics and Institutions, NBER Summer Institute Asset Pricing
meeting, Yale,UC San Diego, University of Illinois Urbana–Champaign, Carnegie Mellon Univer-
sity, UT Dallas, Stockholm School of Economics, and HEC Paris for their valuable inputs. Julien
Sauvagnat gratefully acknowledges financial support from the Agence Nationale de la Recherche–
Investissements d’Avenir (ANR-11-IDEX-0003/Labex Ecodec/ANR-11-LABX-0047). Wewould like
to thank Vincent Tjeng for outstanding research assistance. The authors do not have any potential
conflicts of interest as identified in the Journal of Finance disclosure policy.
1While the focus of this paper is restricted to international trade flows, the term “globalization”
sometimes also encompasses economic and financial integration.
2See, for instance, Broda and Weinstein (2006) and Feenstra and Weinstein (2014) for product
variety at lower prices, Goldberg et al. (2010) and De Loecker et al. (2016) for cheaper intermediate
goods, and Lileeva and Trefler (2010) for access to foreign markets.
DOI: 10.1111/jofi.12780
2391
2392 The Journal of Finance R
example is China’s productivity growth, which has led to a dramatic increase
in its exports to the rest of the world and to the United States in particular,
with both gains for consumers, and negative consequences for manufacturing
employment and wages.3In short, globalization exposes domestic economies
to foreign shocks with heterogeneous effects on households and firms that
complicate the analysis of its overall impact.
In this paper, we study the effects of globalization through the lens of asset
prices. Assets’ exposure to macroeconomic shocks is reflected in risk premia.
We capture firms’ exposure to trade shocks and examine their effects on U.S.
investors’ marginal utility.Our approach relates to recent work that uses infor-
mation from asset markets to evaluate the effects of innovation and technologi-
cal change (see, for instance, Gˆ
arleanu, Panageas, and Yu(2012)). The intuition
is as follows: if the performance of firms exposed to international trade flows
covaries negatively with investors’ marginal utility, these firms will command
a risk premium. This is what we find empirically. This premium can be driven
either by a positive or a negative joint reaction of domestic firms’ performance
and households’ consumption to foreign shocks. Our evidence points to the lat-
ter and indicates that states of the world in which firms suffer from increased
import competition are states in which consumption is dear. In summary, for-
eign shocks are perceived as bad news by the marginal investor.
We measure firms’ exposure to globalization using shipping costs (SC). In
particular, we follow Bernard, Jensen, and Schott (2006b) and exploit import
data to compute the costs associated with shipments, called Cost-Insurance-
Freight, as a percentage of the price paid by importers. We document substan-
tial cross-sectional variation and time-series persistence in SC, consistent with
the idea that this proxy captures structural and slow-moving barriers to trade.
We also show that SC are tightly linked to shipments’ weight-to-value ratio,
and that both measures correlate negatively with firms’ propensity to import
and export, that is, with their exposure to globalization.
We next build portfolios of stocks based on quintiles of SC and analyze their
returns from 1975 to 2015. We find that the zero cost portfolio that is long
stocks in high SC industries and short stocks in low SC industries has aver-
age annual excess returns of 7% and a Sharpe ratio of 35%. To confirm that
this premium does not reflect loadings on well-known risk factors, we estimate
the residual of stock excess returns from the five-factor model of Fama and
French (2015). We find that the low SC portfolio has abnormal returns of 9.7%
annually, and that the high minus low SC portfolio generates negative excess
returns of 13.7% annually. These findings hold for U.S. and European stocks
considered separately, as well as for different subperiods in our sample. Impor-
tantly, they also hold when portfolios are value-weighted, which suggests that
foreign shocks matter for investors’ wealth. We do not find evidence, however,
that investors misunderstand the displacement effect of import competition in
a way that could create a wedge between ex post realized returns and ex ante
3See Amiti et al. (2018) for consumption gains and Pierce and Schott (2016), Autor, Dorn, and
Hanson (2013), and Acemoglu et al. (2015) for effects on employment and wages.
Globalization Risk Premium 2393
expected returns. In particular, we find no systematic differences in earnings
announcement returns for stocks with low and high SC. Moreover, equity ana-
lysts tend to correctly predict the effect of import competition on domestic U.S.
firms. We conclude that the risk of foreign shocks is priced in the cross-section
of expected returns, and that the performance of firms exposed to these shocks
covaries negatively with domestic investors’ marginal utility.
This finding can be interpreted as a positive response of consumption and
cash flows to foreign shocks through higher exports or sourcing opportunities.
Alternatively, this finding may be a negative response of consumption and
cash flows through the displacement of domestic firms by import competition.
We find evidence for the latter interpretation. First, the risk premium is con-
centrated among firms that are likely to suffer from import competition, but
unlikely to benefit greatly from increased export opportunities. Second, the
returns of firms in low SC industries load more negatively on a proxy for for-
eign productivity shocks, especially the returns of firms more likely to suffer
from import competition. Taken together, the results indicate that the price
of the risk of foreign shocks is negative, that is, that consumption responds
negatively to foreign shocks. Given the domestic benefits associated with for-
eign shocks, including gains from variety, lower prices, and enhanced export
opportunities, this finding is a puzzle. It suggests that the displacement risk
associated with foreign shocks outweighs the benefits from the perspective of
domestic investors.
We examine whether this puzzle can be rationalized within a standard two-
country dynamic general equilibrium model `
a la Melitz (2003). To do so, we
first derive the elasticity of domestic profits and the elasticity of export profits
to foreign productivity shocks. The former is negative due to price effects, and
amplified if demand elasticity is high, while export profits benefit from a rise in
demand in the foreign country,although this effect is dampened by the intensity
of competition in the foreign market. The response of domestic households’
utility to foreign productivity shocks trades off two competing effects: a positive
price effect whereby the price of the final consumption index decreases as
import competition intensifies, and an ambiguous wealth effect due to the
change in the value of households’ portfolios. The model predicts that if the
price of risk is negative, the risk premium should be concentrated among small
and less productive firms, and among these firms, in industries with strong
business-stealing effects. We find that all of these predictions hold in the cross-
section of expected returns.
We calibrate the model using standard parameter values and analyze im-
pulse responses of cash flows, valuations, and consumption to positive foreign
productivity shocks. If perfect risk-sharing is allowed across countries, then
households are diversified internationally and consumption always increases
following foreign productivity shocks. The risk premium of firms in low SC
industries is close to zero and the sign of the price of risk is positive, contrary
to our empirical finding that it is negative. Hence, a standard model of trade
with asset prices and perfect risk-sharing fails to rationalize the globalization
risk premium.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT