The Effect of Succession Taxes on Family Firm Investment: Evidence from a Natural Experiment

DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jofi.12224
Date01 April 2015
Published date01 April 2015
THE JOURNAL OF FINANCE VOL. LXX, NO. 2 APRIL 2015
The Effect of Succession Taxes on Family Firm
Investment: Evidence from a Natural Experiment
MARGARITA TSOUTSOURA
ABSTRACT
This paper provides causal evidence on the impact of succession taxes on firm in-
vestment decisions and transfer of control. Using a 2002 policy change in Greece
that substantially reduced the tax on intrafamily transfers of businesses, I show that
succession taxes lead to a more than 40% decline in investment around family succes-
sions, slow sales growth, and a depletion of cash reserves. Furthermore, succession
taxes strongly affect the decision to sell or retain the firm within the family.I conclude
by discussing implications of my findings for firms in the United States and Europe.
DEMOGRAPHIC TRENDS IN both the United States and Europe make firm suc-
cession planning increasingly important for privately held family businesses.1
Each year, an estimated 690,000 firms providing 2.8 million jobs change hands
in the (European union/EU; European Commission (2006)).
Succession taxes, which are incurred during such transfers and are some-
times referred to as transfer taxes, have been at the center of debate. On the
one hand, there are concerns that taxing successions can discourage firm in-
vestment and growth, and may even force entrepreneurs to sell their firms
in order to meet their tax liability. On the other hand, abundant empirical
evidence suggests that inherited firms underperform (Perez-Gonzalez (2006),
Villalonga and Amit (2006), Bennedsen et al. (2007)), which implies that suc-
cession taxes might be too low, that is, provide incentives to keep poorly man-
aged firms within the family (Bloom (2006)). Underlying both these arguments
is a belief that succession taxes may affect firm boundaries and investment.
Margarita Tsoutsoura is with Chicago Booth. I thank the members of my committee, Patrick
Bolton, Charles Calomiris, Daniel Paravisini, and Daniel Wolfenzon, as well as Francisco
P´
erez-Gonz´
alez for their encouragement and support. I also thank Amit Seru for helpful com-
ments. This work also benefited greatly from the comments of participants of the finance seminars
at Boston College, Columbia University, Cornell University, Duke, Harvard Business School, IN-
SEAD, MIT, Northwestern University, NYU, Rice University, SSE, the University of Florida, the
University of North Carolina, the University of Pennsylvania, the University of Virginia, Wash-
ington University in St. Louis, and Yale University, as well as participants at the WFA 2010,
London Business School Transatlantic Conference, and Thammasat International Conference. I
acknowledge financial support by CIBER and the Kauffman Foundation. All errors are my own.
1Prior research shows that founders or their families control the majority of firms around the
world (Faccio and Lang (2002)). Even among public firms, families control 45% of listed interna-
tional firms (La Porta, Lopez-de-Silanes, and Shleifer (1999)) and at least one-third of large U.S.
public firms (Anderson and Reeb (2003)).
DOI: 10.1111/jofi.12224
649
650 The Journal of Finance R
However, systematic empirical evidence that establishes this link is missing.
In this paper, I aim to fill this gap by establishing and quantifying the effect of
succession taxes on entrepreneurs’ succession decisions, investment decisions,
and financial policies.
The challenge in empirically identifying a causal effect of succession taxes on
firm policies is threefold. First, one needs to isolate the effect of succession taxes
from other possible factors that might affect firm policies around successions
(e.g., the ability of the new owner or aggregate trends). Second, endogeneity
of the decision to transfer the company to family members must be addressed.
Finally, an exogenous source of variation in the tax environment is required.
To overcome these challenges, I exploit a 2002 tax reform in Greece that
reduced succession tax rates for transfers of limited liability companies to fam-
ily members from 20% to less than 2.4%.2I begin by constructing a unique
database that contains information on all transfers of limited liability firms
in Greece for the years 1999 to 2005. Although limited liability firms are pri-
vate, they are required to publish their ownership changes as well as their
financial statements. I then supplement these data by matching them to hand-
collected data on the gender of each entrepreneur’s first-born child and on each
entrepreneur’s personal income from other sources.
In the quasi-experimental setting provided by the tax policy change, I em-
ploy two methodologies to measure the effect of the policy change on invest-
ment. First I apply difference-in-difference-in-differences (DDD) to analyze the
change in investment around successions in response to the tax policy change.
I compare firms that undergo a family succession (the treated group) to firms
transferred to unrelated entrepreneurs (the control group) both before and
after the policy change. This method controls for aggregate trends and other
succession-induced changes in investment. Furthermore, by comparing the two
groups before and after the tax reform, the analysis disentangles the effect of
the identity of the new owner (family or unrelated) from the effect of the suc-
cession tax.
A major concern with the DDD approach is that the family versus unrelated
succession decision is unlikely to be independent of firm characteristics related
to investment opportunities. Toaddress this concern, I use the gender of the de-
parting entrepreneur’s first-born child as an instrument for family succession,
as in Bennedsen et al. (2007)). The gender of the departing entrepreneur’s first-
born child is a plausible instrument for family successions because it affects the
probability of a family succession and is unlikely to be correlated with a firm’s
investment opportunities. As before, I compare firms that undergo a family suc-
cession to firms transferred to unrelated entrepreneurs both before and after
the policy change, but I use the instrument to randomly assign firms into the
two groups. Thus, the identification exploits two sources of variation: the tax
reform provides time-series variation with respect to the transfer tax, whereas
the instrument provides exogenous cross-sectional variation with respect to
the succession decision. This method allows for causal inference because, as
2The tax rate remained unchanged at 20% for unrelated transfers.
Effect of Succession Taxes on Family Firm Investment 651
before, it disentangles the effect of the new owner’s identity from the effect of
the succession tax, while also addressing concerns regarding endogeneity of
the succession decision.
Both the DDD and the instrumental variable (IV) estimates reveal a
negative effect of transfer taxes on postsuccession investment for firms trans-
ferred within the family.In the presence of higher succession taxes, investment
drops from 17.6% of property, plant, and equipment (PPE) three years before
succession to 9.7% of PPE two years after. This impact of succession taxes
on investment is economically large: the implied decline in investment ratio
(0.079) is approximately 40% of the pretransition level of investment. For these
firms, successions are also associated with a decrease in cash reserves, a de-
cline in profitability, and slower sales growth. Note that, to the extent that
entrepreneurs can plan ahead for the succession and the related tax liability,
the estimates I report in the paper likely underestimate the true effect of suc-
cession taxes. Nevertheless, I obtain similar results when limiting attention
to death-related successions—instances in which succession planning is less
likely.
I also find a strong relation between succession taxes and the decision to sell
or keep the firm within the family.After the reduction in inheritance taxes, fam-
ily successions increase from 45.2% of all transfers before the reform to 73.9%,
a more than 63% increase. This evidence shows that succession taxes signifi-
cantly influence the allocation of firm ownership and thus firm boundaries. This
finding has potentially important implications, given existing evidence in the
literature that inherited family firms underperform. In particular, to the extent
that lower succession taxes provide incentives to allocate assets to low-ability
heirs, tax policy that changes such taxes could impact aggregate productivity
and economic growth (Morck, Stangeland, and Yeung (2000), Bloom (2006),
Bennedsen et al. (2007), Bloom and Van Reenen (2007)).
The final part of the analysis investigates whether the effect of succession
taxes on investment varies with observed firm characteristics. I find that the
results continue to hold for both large and small firms in my sample. However,
when I run the analysis separately for low versus high asset tangibility, I find
that the observed effects are stronger for family firms with low asset tangibility.
The effects are also stronger for firms owned by entrepreneurs with relatively
low income from other sources, and as a result may have no alternative sources
of financing apart from costly external finance. This evidence is consistent
with financial constraints exacerbating the effects of succession taxes on firm
investment. However, care should be taken in interpreting the results, as these
patterns may also be consistent with other plausible channels.
This paper connects to several strands of the literature. First, it contributes
to the literature on family firms. Understanding what factors affect firm poli-
cies around successions is important because the way in which firm control
is passed from one generation to the next can critically affect the develop-
ment and growth of the firm. The literature so far highlights three factors that
can affect intergenerational transfers of family firms: nepotism (Burkart, Pa-
nunzi, and Shleifer (2003), Caselli and Gennaioli (2005), Perez-Gonzalez (2006),

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT