The Effect of Performance Standards on Health Care Provider Behavior: Evidence from Kidney Transplantation

Published date01 December 2016
Date01 December 2016
AuthorRichard A. Hirth,Sarah S. Stith
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jems.12161
The Effect of Performance Standards on Health
Care Provider Behavior: Evidence from Kidney
Transplantation
SARAH S. STITH
Department of Economics
University of New Mexico
Albuquerque, NM
ssstith@unm.edu
RICHARD A. HIRTH
Department of Health Management and Policy, School of Public Health
University of Michigan
Ann Arbor, MI
rhirth@umich.edu
Performance standards are designed to ensure a basic level of quality,and through public reporting
of firm performance, encourage firms to compete on quality thus allowing the market to determine
the optimal level of quality. In markets with substantial excess demand, however, demand effects
may be insufficient to induce any change in firm behavior and enforcement may be required to
ensure high quality. Even with enforcement, quality still may not improve at underperforming
firms if gaming the system is less costly than improving quality.We test whether information alone
or with regulatory enforcement improves outcomes or elicits gaming behavior in our study of 266
kidney transplant centers between 2001 and 2012. In a context of excess demand induced by price
controls, we show that information alone has no impact and enforcement may actually increase
market inefficiencies; firms respond to costly quality requirements, not by improving quality,but
by reducing supply, which exacerbates the disequilibrium between supply and demand, and by
cream-skimming, which reduces access to transplantation among sicker patients.
1. INTRODUCTION
The use of publicly reported quality data by regulators theoretically should address
market failures associated with a lack of competition and incomplete information, thus
increasing market efficiency including improvements in quality. Consumers will make
better informed choices leading to increased competition among firms and overall qual-
ity should increase by avoiding the low-quality equilibrium predicted in Akerlof’s (1970)
paper on used cars. Public and/or private reporting of product or service quality oc-
curs in many sectors (e.g., automobile safety test data are reported by the National
Wethank the Robert Wood Johnson Foundation Center for Health Policy at the University of New Mexico and
the Ross School of Business at the University of Michigan for the financial support necessary to purchase the
data used in this paper as well as Tom Buchmueller, Brady Horn, Alan Leichtman, Lauren Nicholas, seminar
attendees at IUPUI and the RWJF Center for Health Policy,and participants at the Fifth Biennial Conference of
the American Society of Health Economics for helpful comments. In addition, “this work is supported in part
by Health Resources and Services Administration contract 234-2005-370011C. The content is the responsibility
of the authors alone and does not necessarily reflect the views or policies of the Department of Health and
Human Services, nor does mention of trade names, commercial products,or organizations imply endorsement
by the U.S. Government.” http://optn.transplant.hrsa.gov/data/citing.asp
C2016 Wiley Periodicals, Inc.
Journal of Economics & Management Strategy, Volume25, Number 4, Winter 2016, 789–825
790 Journal of Economics & Management Strategy
Highway Traffic Safety Administration whereasquality reviews and reliability data are
reported by private sector organizations such as the Consumers Union). However,qual-
ity reporting and standards are particularly prevalent in health care due to the extent
of information asymmetry between producers and consumers and the significant (and
often irreversible) consequences of receiving poor quality care. More broadly, quality
reporting is a key component of a health care policy strategy to overcome market failure
by empowering consumers to be agents of change in efforts to improve quality and
contain costs. When quality standards are enforced by regulators, in addition to public
reporting of quality, the incentives for firms to provide high-quality services should be
further increased. However, demand side responses might decrease with enforcement
if consumers can depend on regulators to ensure quality.
Unfortunately,many such regulated markets (e.g., in health care) suffer from addi-
tional market failures that make the implications of quality reporting and enforcement
less obvious. For example, and as we will test in this paper, if the introduction of pub-
lic quality reporting occurs in a market with significant excess demand, any consumer
response will be insufficient to induce a change in firm behavior. Introducing quality
enforcement without any change in the price will likely only exacerbate the disparity
between supply and demand as firms choose not to serve their less profitable customers.
Such cream-skimming behavior could be further exacerbated in the presence of insuffi-
cient risk adjustment or if the quality measure is difficult for firms to affect.
In transplantation, some form of quality monitoring, based on one-year posttrans-
plant patient and organ graft survival, has existed since 1991. Beginning in 2001, this
information has been publicly available online through the Scientific Registry of Trans-
plant Recipients (SRTR) with new reports issued every six months for all transplant
programs.1The standards are monitored by the Department of Health and Human Ser-
vices through the Organ Procurementand Transplantation Network (OPTN). The OPTN
generally has taken an advisory rather than punitive role with transplant centers that
failed to meet the survival standards. In response to concerns about a lack of enforcement
by the OPTN, the Centers for Medicare and Medicaid Services (CMS) began enforcing
the OPTN quality standards with the threat of an expensive audit and possible closure of
noncompliant transplant centers, starting on June 28, 2007 (CMS, 2007). Other insurers
also require that centers meet these or stricter standards in order to remain part of their
provider network.
Using a simple model of the supply and demand for kidney transplants, we pre-
dict that information alone will be insufficient to cause a change in supplier behavior,
primarily due to the existence of significant excess demand induced by a price ceiling. In
the presence of enforcement, we expect centers to improve outcomes primarily through
gaming behaviors; they will do so both when noncompliant and preemptively when
approaching noncompliance.
As our model predicts, we find no impact from information alone. All our results
are only statistically significant after June 28, 2007, when CMS increased its oversight of
transplantation. Enforcement leads to more cautious behavior at the average transplant
center and induces a significant gaming response in noncompliant centers or centers
approaching noncompliance. Our results indicate, however, that despite a strategic re-
sponse from transplant centers, no evidence of a statistically significant improvement
in reported posttransplant survival rates exists. We only see evidence of changes in
“gaming” outcomes. Noncompliant centers decrease transplant rates for both deceased
1. http://www.srtr.org.
Health Care Provider Behavior 791
and live donor transplants and increase the number of patients removed from the wait-
list as too sick for transplant or transferred to another center. We also find evidence of
preemptive behavior based on the publicly posted information in the CMS enforcement
period; centers respond to almost breaching survival thresholds in a similar but muted
manner relative to their response to reports documenting regulatory noncompliance.
Our theoretical prediction that any demand shift will not impact the quantity or quality
of transplants (due to excess demand) and the lack of any effect on outcomes prior to
the introduction of CMS enforcement suggests that transplant center responses are the
primary drivers of our results and affecting demand does not have a meaningful impact
on providers, as long as the regulated price falls far below the market clearing price.
Our predictions for the effects of information on supply and enforce-
ment/noncompliance on demand arise from market features that are not unique to
kidney transplantation. Shifts in demand with the availability of information can be ex-
pected in other industries with significant asymmetric information, such as insurance,
pharmaceuticals, and investment banking. Imperfect competition leading to downward
sloping demand curves is the rule, not the exception, in essentially all markets. Price
controls (or excessive quality) lead to excess demand, the main reason why information
alone is not enough. Such controls exist in many markets, especially within health care
due to the ubiquitous use of Diagnosis-Related Groups in the United States, which pay
the same for a given procedure (e.g., kidney transplant, cardiac bypass surgery) regard-
less of the actual costs incurred. Maybe even more significantly, many countries have
national health insurance systems that explicitly control prices and/or facility budgets
(e.g., the United Kingdom and Canada), leading to waiting lists for many services be-
yond transplantation, suggesting that similar dynamics could occur much more broadly.
Even in the United States, Medicaid patients often face similar access issues as in coun-
tries with national health insurance systems. In addition, most transplant centers are
located in not-for-profit hospitals, as is common in other countries, and as is common
among larger hospitals (greater than one hundred beds) in the United States.2
In terms of the use and implications of quality measures, transplantation is also
not unique. By definition, any payment change from volume of care (traditional fee-for-
service payment) to value-based purchasing requires metrics other than units of services
delivered. Quality/performance measures are often specifically rewarded, and even
when they are not, as in some bundled payment systems, quality needs to be monitored
implicitly or explicitly to ensure against unintended consequences. Although we study
one specific context, the issues we raise (topped out measures, intrinsic competition on
quality/performance, gaming of measures) have been shown to arise both theoretically
and empirically in health care and beyond (Heckman et al., 2011).
Prior U.S.-focused studies in health economics focus on the importance of informa-
tion availability (through report cards) without enforcement of performance standards.
In general, these studies use data on coronary artery bypass graft surgery, a complex
medical procedure with comparable short-run mortality rates to those in kidney trans-
plantation, the most common and least complex type of organ transplantation.3We
2. The 2007 American Hospital Association survey,which includes 231 of the 239 kidney transplant centers
operating in 2007 based on the OPTN data, shows that 72% of kidney transplant centers are in not-for-profit
hospitals, 20% in government-owned, and 8% in for-profit. This differs from the general sample of hospitals
in the 2007 AHA data, but if we restrict the sample of AHA hospitals to just to larger hospitals (over 100 total
beds), which includes all but two transplant centers, the non-kidney transplant center ownership types are
similar to those in kidney transplantation with 65% not-for-profit, 19% government-owned, and 16% for-profit.
3. Our results are arguably more geographically generalizable than the results in the existing literature.
Although heart disease does exceed kidney disease in prevalence, the report card initiatives studied in the

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT