The Effect of CEO Option Compensation on the Capital Structure: A Natural Experiment

AuthorOnur Kemal Tosun
Published date01 December 2016
Date01 December 2016
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/fima.12116
The Effect of CEO Option Compensation
on the Capital Structure: A Natural
Experiment
Onur Kemal Tosun
Firms simultaneously chooseboth their capital and their executive compensation structure. Using
the Internal Revenue Code 162(m) tax law as an exogenous shock to compensation structure in a
natural experiment setting, I identify firm leverage changes as a result of chief executive officer
(CEO) option compensation changes. The evidence provides strong support for debt agency
theory. Firmsappear to decrease leverage when CEOs are paid with moreoptions and when CEO
options become a higher percentage of future cash flows. The findings are robust to controlling
for corporate governanceand convertible debt.
Numerous studies have examined the relation between chief executive officer (CEO) option
pay and firm capital structure choice. Some examine the relation between CEO option pay and
leverage using leverage as the dependent variable,explicitly assuming that pay structure variation
causes differences in observed firm leverage. Others use option compensation as the dependent
variable and investigate how it varies with the leverage decision. The empirical challenge is that
these are both firm choices that are arguably made simultaneously. Therefore, it is difficult to
identify the cause of this relation from the existing literature. In this article, I use an exogenous
shock that influences only CEO option compensation. Subsequently, I examine how changes
in option pay resulting from that shock affect the capital structure. This allows me to identify
whether changes in compensation structure cause changes in leverage ratios.
Specifically, my main research question is how CEO option compensation influences the
capital structure decision. There is substantial disagreement over the nature of this relation.
Bryan, Hwang, and Lilien (2000), Hassan and Hosino (2008), Andrikopoulos (2009), and Sepe
(2010) claim there is a negative relation between option pay and the leverage decision. Relying
on debt agency theory, these studies report a decreasing effect of CEO option compensation on
leverage. Jensen and Meckling (1976) suggest that stock options align CEO interests with those
of shareholders to mitigate agency problems between managers and shareholders. Debtholders,
however, demand higher returns because CEOs with high option payments have incentives to
increase stock price volatility by investing in riskier projects (see, e.g., Agrawal and Mandelker,
1987; DeFusco, Johnson, and Zorn, 1990), potentially transferring wealth from bondholders to
shareholders. Hence, to optimize the cost of debt, firms paying a large proportion of option-based
compensation optimally reduce leverage.
I appreciate the valuable comments from Raghu Rau (Editor) and an anonymous referee. I gratefully acknowledge the
contribution of Michael Faulkender, Gordon Phillips, Lemma Senbet, Gerard Hoberg, and seminar participants at the
University of Maryland, University of Kentucky,University of Warwick, University of Cambridge, Norwegian School of
Economics, Norwegian Business School, and Ozyegin University.All errors are my own.
Onur Kemal Tosun is an Assistant Professor of Finance in Warwick Business School at University of Warwick, United
Kingdom.
Financial Management Winter 2016 pages 953 – 979
954 Financial Management rWinter 2016
In contrast, relying on managerial agency theory arguments, Lewellen, Loderer, and Martin
(1987), Berger,Ofek, and Yermack (1997), MacMinn and Page (2006), Coles, Daniel, and Naveen
(2006), and Tchistyi, Yermack, and Yun(2011) argue in favor of a positive relation between CEO
option pay and leverage.If debtholders are not fully aware of CEO pay composition and its wealth-
shifting implications, CEOs with large option pay components choose to increase leverage.
Finally, other studies argue there is no relation between CEO option payand leverage. Yermack
(1995) and Mehran (1995), for example, do not find evidence of a significant relation between
equity-based pay and leverage. Hayes, Lemmon, and Qui (2012) examine the link between option
pay and risk-taking behaviorby using Financial Accounting Standards (FAS) 123R and the change
in accounting treatment of options, but they do not find a strong relation between the decline in
option pay and less risky investments.
I analyze an exogenous shock to CEO compensation structure, specifically, Section 162(m)
of the Internal Revenue Code (IRC 162(m)). The Revenue Reconciliation Act of 1993 added
Section 162(m) to restrict the corporate tax deduction for executive compensation to $1 million.
It contains an exception for performance-based compensation:
. . . In the case of any publicly held corporation, no deduction shall be allowedunder this chapter
for applicable employee remuneration with respect to any covered employee to the extent that
the amount of such remuneration for the taxable year with respect to such employee exceeds
$ 1,000,000. . . .
Consequently,beginning January 1, 1994, companies have largely adjusted their compensation
packages so that pay over $1 million qualifies under the performance-based exception. That
change primarily occurs in the form of increased option compensation. IRC 162(m) should
have no direct influence on the capital structure. This tax deduction limitation and the link
to performance-based compensation should not alter the tax benefits, f inancial distress costs,
information asymmetry, or market timing motivations of a firm when determining its optimal
capital structure. Hence, I use IRC 162(m) as a valid instrument for the exogenous shock in the
natural experiment. Moreover, IRC 162(m) is not a binding constraint for all companies because
only firms paying the CEO a cash salary of $1 million or more are affected. This binding constraint
enables me to compare these treatment firms (those paying at least $1 million in salary) with the
control companies before and after the exogenous shock using a triple difference-in-difference
analysis. I also compare firms in the pre-period with fir ms in the post-period.
I find that the increase in CEO option compensation has a mitigating effect on the general
trend of increasing leverage across firms. In particular, firms decrease leverage as the proportion
of CEO option compensation increases and as those options become a higher percentage of
the firm’s future cash flows. Moreover, firms reduce leverage as the value of the CEO option
compensation goes up. The findings are consistent with debt agency theory arguments.
I also address possible concerns about the natural experiment and alternative explanations for
the findings. Although the 162(m) tax law is an exogenous event for firms, it might be argued
that companies anticipated its occurrence and behaved accordingly. For example, firms might
have increased option pay and issued more debt before the tax law change. I show this is not the
case because the treatment firms (those with CEO salary of at least $1 million) and control f irms
show no rapid increase in option pay before the law. In addition, leverage appears to increase not
only for treatment firms but also for control fir ms before the shock. Additional placebo tests for
the period before the exogenous event should capture any significant anticipation by firms and
show there is no such anticipation.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT