The Economics of Tacit Collusion:Implications for Merger Control

Published date01 April 2007
Date01 April 2007
DOIhttps://doi.org/10.1016/S0573-8555(06)82008-0
Pages217-239
AuthorMarc Ivaldi,Bruno Jullien,Patrick Rey,Paul Seabright,Jean Tirole
CHAPTER 8
The Economics of Tacit Collusion:
Implications for Merger Control1
Marc Ivaldi, Bruno Jullien, Patrick Rey, Paul Seabright and Jean Tirole
IDEI, Toulouse,France
8.1. Introduction
Tacit collusion refers to a group of oligopolists’ ability to coordinate, evenin the
absence of explicit agreement,2to raise price or more generally increase profit
at the detriment of consumers. It has been treated under the notion of collective
dominance in a number of important European Court decisions and under the
“coordinated effects” label in the US. The present chapter focuses on the eco-
nomic analysis of the impact of mergers on collusion and its consequences for
anti-trust policy.3
The legal treatment of collusion depends on the form it takes: explicit, tacit,
or any combination of the two. Explicit collusion or cartel agreements are usu-
ally banned under antitrust laws, such as Section 8.1 of the US Sherman Act
or Article 81 of the European Treaty. The treatment of tacit collusion has how-
ever been subject to more controversy than that of cartels, due the absence of a
formal agreement or explicit coordination.4For this reason the use of the con-
cept of tacit collusion has almost exclusively been used in merger control policy.
Moreover the European Commission has relied more heavily on it than the US
anti-trust authorities. This can be attributed mostly to the difference in the legal
procedures. While the Clayton Act prohibits a merger the effect of which “may
substantially lessen competition”, until recently, the European mergerregulation
allowed the Commission to declare incompatible with the EC treaties merg-
ers that “create or strengthen a dominant position as a result of which effective
1This chapter is based on a report on collective dominance for the European Commission (Ivaldi
et al., 2003). We thank Vivek Ghosal and John Martin for comments and references.
2“Tacit collusion” need not involveany “collusion” in the legal sense, and in particular need in-
volve no communication between the parties. A better term from a legal perspectivemight be “tacit
coordination”.
3See our report (Ivaldi et al., 2003) for a more complete analysis.
4See in particular the US Supreme Court opinion in Brooke Group, Ltd. v. Brown & Williamson
Tobacco Corp (1993) or the appeal decision in WilliamsonOil Co. v. Philip Morris USA (Eleventh
District, 2003). For the European Community, see the annulment by the Court of Justice of the
Commission Decision 85/202/EEC (the Woodpulp case).
CONTRIBUTIONS TO ECONOMIC ANALYSIS © 2007 ELSEVIER B.V.
VOLUME 282 ISSN: 0573-8555 ALL RIGHTS RESERVED
DOI: 10.1016/S0573-8555(06)82008-0
218 M. Ivaldi et al.
competition would be significantly impeded”, where dominance can be single
or collective. While the treatment of mergers in the US has mostly focused on
unilateral effects, with a minor role for coordinated effects, due to lack of clar-
ity in the interpretation of collective dominance, the European Commission has
in the past preferred to address issues of tacit collusion when dealing with col-
lective dominance with no structural links.5Only recently has the new Merger
regulation6of 2004 allowed the commission to address unilateral effects in a
more systematic way, by prohibiting a concentration which would “significantly
impede effective competition”.7
In this chapter, we review the main industry characteristics that affect collu-
sion. We then draw some implications for merger policy. Section 8.2 introduces
the concept of tacit collusion, while the factors that are relevant for collusion
are discussed in Section 8.3. Section 8.4 proposes a mathematical illustration.
Section 8.5 discusses non-price collusion. Finally Section 8.6 focuses on the
implications for the practice of merger control.
8.2. The economics of tacit collusion
Tacit collusion can arise when firms interact repeatedly. They may then be able
to maintain high prices through the threat that any deviation from the collusive
path would trigger some retaliation. To be sustainable, retaliation must be suf-
ficiently likely and costly to outweigh the short-term benefits from “cheating”
on the collusive path. These short-term benefits, as well as the magnitude and
likelihood of retaliation, depend in turn on the characteristics of the industry.
Retaliation refers to the firms’ reaction to a deviation from the collusive path.
A simple form of retaliation consists in the breakdown of collusion and the
restoration of “normal” competition and profits. Firms anticipate that if one at-
tempts to reap short-term profits, they will be no more collusion in the future.
Firms may then abide to the current collusive prices in order to keep the collu-
sion going, in which case collusion is self-sustaining. This form of collusion has
a simple interpretation: firms trust each other to maintain collusive prices; but
if one of them deviates, trust vanishes and all firms start acting in their short-
term interest. However, there may be more sophisticated forms of retaliation
that may inflict tougher punishments, thereby allowing sustaining higher collu-
sive prices. Another reason why returning forever to “normal competition” may
5Leading cases for EU are Gencor/Lonrho (M.619), Nestlé/Perrier (M.190) or Airtours/First
Choice (M.1524). In the US, the FTC has recently and unsuccessfully attempted to challenge a
merger on the ground of coordinated effects (FTC v.Arch Coal, 2004).
6Council Regulation (EC) No 139/2004 of 20 January 2004 on the control of concentrations be-
tween undertakings (the EC Merger Regulation), Official Journal, L 24, 29.01.2004, pages 1–22.
7Another difference between the US and the EU concerns the proceedings: in the US a merger
can only be challenged before a court, whereas in the EU the procedure is internal to the European
Commission; the separation between investigation and decision is thus less clearin that case, despite
the scrutiny of the member States and the fact that the final decision is made by the Commissioners.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT