Saving Section 2: Reframing U.S.Monopolization Law

Published date01 April 2007
Pages417-451
Date01 April 2007
DOIhttps://doi.org/10.1016/S0573-8555(06)82016-X
AuthorTimothy J. Brennan
CHAPTER 16
Saving Section 2: Reframing U.S.
Monopolization Law
Timothy J. Brennan
Professor of Public Policyand Economics, University of Maryland Baltimore County;
Senior Fellow,Resources for the Future
E-mail address: brennan@umbc.edu
16.1. Section 2’s unfortunate distinctiveness
Antitrust policy famously divides into three categories: collusion, monopoliza-
tion, and mergers. In the United States, three very long-standing statutes initially
set out these categories, respectively Sections 1 and 2 of the Sherman Act (1890)
and Section 7 of the Clayton Act (1914).1These statutes, known in antitrust by
their section numbers, are notoriously short. Section 1 proscribes “every con-
tract, combination ...or conspiracy in restraint of trade;” Section 2 finds guilty
“every person who shall monopolize, attempt to monopolize, or ...combine or
conspire to monopolize;” and Section 7 prohibits asset acquisitions that “may
be substantially to lessen competition or to tend to create a monopoly.” The op-
erational content of these brief statutes is defined by the case law arising from
the public and private enforcement actions brought under them. Their ability to
remain a vital part of U.S. economic policy rests in their brevity and the ability
of case law to adapt them to changed circumstances and advances in knowledge.
Relatively speaking, collusion and merger law as set out in Section 1 and
Section 7 cases is uncontroversial within fairly broad margins, primarily be-
cause their focus, not necessarily exclusive, is on horizontal dealings among
competitors that suppress competition. Collusion cases under Section 1, partic-
ularly the per se violations of fixing prices and allocating markets, present the
clearest examples (Shenefield and Stelzer, 1998, pp. 43–50). Apart from liber-
tarian critiques based on freedom of contract (Armentano, 1982) and what might
be regarded as a generous view of the ability of free entry to cure all ills (Dewey,
1979), there is little dispute that horizontal collusion should be deterred. Inves-
tigations tend to focus more on factual questions such as whether there was a
conspiracy and by how much did it raise price than on theoretical analyses of
whether practices are harmful.
115 U.S.C. §§1, 2, 18.
CONTRIBUTIONS TO ECONOMIC ANALYSIS © 2007 ELSEVIER B.V.
VOLUME 282 ISSN: 0573-8555 ALL RIGHTS RESERVED
DOI: 10.1016/S0573-8555(06)82016-X
418 T.J.Brennan
There are margins of dispute, to be sure. “Rule of reason” Section 1 cases
often require delicate judgments about whether a nominally restrictive practice is
necessary to achieve greater benefits,2but those inquiries again tend to rest more
on the factual strength of an efficiency defense than on a fundamental policy
dispute.3Non-horizontal agreements, such as resale price maintenance and tie-
ins, are more problematic. For our purposes, we treat those here as variants of
monopolization.4
A similar rough consensus surrounds mergers, particular horizontal merg-
ers. The consensus on why such mergers are problematic, and how to analyze
them, constitutes the Department of Justice (DOJ) and Federal Trade Commis-
sion (FTC) Horizontal Merger Guidelines (HMGs) (DOJ, 1997). The underlying
consensus is reflected in the incorporation of these guidelines in merger analyses
taken throughout the government, e.g., in the FERC Merger Policy Statement
(FERC, 1996). This is not to suggest that merger cases are uncontroversial,
but that the root of the controversial is largely factual rather than on the prin-
ciple of how and perhaps whether cases should be brought (Eckbo and Weir,
1985;Crandall and Winston, 2003;Baker, 2003;Werden, 2004). Disputes fun-
damentally involve market delineation—the determination of who competes
with whom, and whether entry is likely to mitigate any problems created by
otherwise undue concentration.
Surrounding this question are other difficult issues involving the identifica-
tion of the mechanism of competitive harm (unilateral or coordinated effects)
(DOJ, 1997 at 2.1, 2.2),5the construction and relevance of differentiated prod-
uct simulation models (Froeb and Werden, 1996;Baker and Rubinfeld, 1999),
and other methods for estimating propensity of merged firms to reduce output
(Harris and Simons, 1989;Katz and Shapiro, 2003;O’Brien and Wickelgren,
2003). A more fundamental dispute is perhaps whether the appropriate measure
of welfare is total or just consumer welfare (Lande, 1982;Ross and Winter,
2004;Competition Bureau, 2004, §§8.5, 8.25–28, 8.31–35). But as with collu-
sion, there is relatively little conceptual (as opposed to empirical) dispute except
perhaps for mergers going beyond the market of the involved parties (Brennan,
2004b). Those, too, fall for our purposes here within the monopolization cate-
gory.
Monopolization cases, primarily but not exclusively brought under Section 2,
differ from both collusion and merger cases in being controversial at the more
2Broadcast Music Inc., et al., v. Columbia Broadcasting System et al., 441 U.S. 1 (1979).
3One could apply efficiency defenses even in per se cases (Clyde and Reitzes, 2004), but we do
not typically do so (Baker, 1991;Brennan, 2000).
4Exclusionary practices may be addressed under Section 1 and Section 2, and sometimes may be
found illegal under the latter yet legal under the former.U.S. et al. v. Microsoft Corp. (“Microsoft”),
87 F. Supp. 2d. 30 (D.C.D.C. 2000), direct appeal to the Supreme Court denied, 530 U.S. 1301
(2000); aff’d in part, r’vsd in part and remanded, 253 F. 3d. 34 (D.C. Circ. 2001); final judgment
entered, 2002 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 22864 (2002).
5Mergers leading to a less competitive oligopoly are included in the “unilateral” category
(Scheffman and Coleman, 2003, p. 323).
Saving Section 2: Reframing U.S. Monopolization Law 419
fundamental level of whether such cases should even be considered. Monop-
olization typically involves foreclosure or exclusion, the idea that actual or
potential rivals are precluded from competing in some market. These cases typ-
ically take the form of “abuse of dominance,”6where input or complementary
product suppliers (e.g., retailers) are threatened by a firm with market power
that its product will not be available, or only available at high prices, unless
those supplier sign exclusive contracts, accept tied products, or adopt similar
practices that keep out other entrants by “raising rivals’ costs” (RRC).7Atra-
ditional monopolization concern has been when vertical mergers or restraints
would restrict competition. A focus of some recent Section 2 cases has been the
use of discounts, particularly involving bundles of products, as a way to discour-
age buyers from turning to competitors.8
Unlike collusion and (horizontal) mergers, monopolization has been a per-
sistently controversial practice, for reasons familiar to those engaged in antitrust
policy debates over the last twenty-five years. Normally, firms cut prices without
taking into account the adverse effects on competitors’ profits. Increasing price
involves inhibition of independent action among competitors, i.e., sellers in the
same market. Vertical dealings or other relationships between firms in separate
markets should be largely irrelevant. Vertical integration and restraints have to
do with the internal organization of production; they do not expand coverage
over a market.
The “Chicago” critique pointed out that forcing buyers to do certain things,
such as accept tied goods or use only selected retailers, reduces demand for the
product, implying a justification based on cutting costs, raising quality, or im-
proving the marketing of the product. Penalizing firms, even monopolies, for
bundling, discounting, or charging low prices is to penalize them for doing what
competitive firms are supposed to do. Central to all of these concerns is that if
competition is also about beating rivals in a market, monopolization law may
protect competitors at the expense of competition, harming the public that com-
petition is nominally supposed to benefit.
An initial goal is to understand why monopolization law differs from col-
lusion and merger law in the quality and level of controversy. For example, is
62002 O.J. (C325) 65 (2002). Facey and Assaf (2002) provide a useful review of monopolization
law in the U.S., the European Union, and Canada.
7U.S. v. Dentsply (“Dentsply”) 277 F. Supp. 2d 387 (D.C. Del. 2003), r’vsd and
remanded, 399 F.3d 181 (3rd Circ. 2005); Microsoft, supra note 4; European Com-
mission, Case Comp/C-3/37.792 Microsoft, Mar. 3, 2004. http://europa.eu.int/comm/
competition/antitrust/cases/decisions/37792/en.pdf. For more on raising rivals’ costs, see
Krattenmaker and Salop (1986).
8Concord Boat Corp. v. Brunswick Corp., 207 F.3d 1039 (8th Cir. 2000), cert. denied, 531 U.S.
979 (2000) (Brunswick’s purchase share and absolute volume discounts for purchasesof motor boat
engines were found legal as above cost, with no implicit tying in the sales of different types of
engines); LePage’s, Inc. v.3M (“LePage’s”), 324 F.3d 141 (3d Cir.Pa., 2003), cert. denied 124 S.
Ct. 2932 (2004) (3M’s discounting of bundled wholesale sales of trademarked (Scotch) and store-
brand tape excluded LePages from retail outlets).

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT