The Downside of Asset Screening for Market Liquidity

Date01 October 2017
AuthorVICTORIA VANASCO
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jofi.12519
Published date01 October 2017
THE JOURNAL OF FINANCE VOL. LXXII, NO. 5 OCTOBER 2017
The Downside of Asset Screening for Market
Liquidity
VICTORIA VANASCO
ABSTRACT
This paper explores the tension between asset quality and market liquidity. I model
an originator who screens assets whose cash flows are later sold in secondary markets.
Screening improves asset quality but gives rise to asymmetric information, hindering
trade of the asset cash flows. In the optimal mechanism (second-best), costly retention
of cash flows is essential to implement asset screening. Market allocations can feature
too much or too little screening relative to second-best, where too much screening gen-
erates inefficiently illiquid markets. Furthermore, the economy is prone to multiple
equilibria. The optimal mechanism is decentralized with two tools: retention rules
and transfers.
SECONDARY MARKETS FOR ASSETS PLAY an important role in providing lending
capacity to the financial industry and the real economy, by allowing finan-
cial institutions to raise funds through asset sales. In 2007 more than 25% of
outstanding consumer credit in the United States was financed through the
securitization of consumer loans.1Following the financial crash of 2008, how-
ever, issuance of securitized assets collapsed, adversely affecting financial in-
stitutions and, in turn, firms and consumers’ access to credit (Chodorow-Reich
(2014), Mondragon (2015)). In response, policy makers geared their efforts
Victoria Vanascois from the Graduate School of Business, Stanford University. I thank Bruno
Biais (Editor), the Associate Editor, and two anonymous referees. I am also thankful to Vladimir
Asriyan, Mitch Berlin (discussant), Peter DeMarzo, Sebastian Di Tella,Darrel Duffie, Dana Foarta,
Alex Frankel, William Fuchs, Pierre-Olivier Gourinchas, Brett Green, Laurie Hodrick, Amir
Kermani, Arvind Krishnamurthy, Ulrike Malmendier, Takeshi Murooka, Aniko ¨
Oery, Christine
Parlour,Giorgia Piacentino, Demian Pouzo, David Romer, Nancy Wallace, and YaoZeng for insight-
ful discussions and suggestions; seminar participants at UC Berkeley Department of Economics,
Haas School of Business, GSB at Stanford University, The Fuqua School of Business, University
of Maryland, Universita Bocconi, EIEF Rome, CREI and Universitat Pompeu Fabra, University
of Toronto, HEC Paris, Columbia Business School, Wharton School of Business, the New York and
Richmond Federal Reserves, the Federal Reserve Board, and the European Central Bank; and
conference participants at the FTG Meeting at UCLA (2014), the Econometric Society Meetings
in Madrid (2014), FIRS (2015), and UTDT Economics Conference (2015). I acknowledge financial
support from The Clayman Institute for Gender Research and I declare that I have no relevant or
material financial interests related to the research in this paper. All errors are my own.
1Securitization is the practice of creating and selling securities whose payoffs are derived from
and collateralized by a specified pool of underlying assets. Some common examples include (com-
mercial) mortgage-backed securities ((C)MBS), collaterilized loan obligations (CLO), and asset-
backed securities (ABS).
DOI: 10.1111/jofi.12519
1937
1938 The Journal of Finance R
toward reviving these markets.2Two key market frictions have been brought
to light. First, the ability to sell loan cash flows in secondary markets (directly or
through securitization) has been associated with a decline in lending standards
(see Berndt and Gupta (2008) for the syndicated loan market, and DellAriccia,
Igan, and Laeven (2012), Elul (2016), Jaffee et al. (2009), Keys et al. (2010), and
Mian and Sufi (2009) for the mortgage market). Second, originators have used
private information about loan quality when choosing which loans to securi-
tize (Downing, Jaffee, and Wallace (2008), Calem, Henderson, and Liles (2011),
Agarwal, Chang, and Yavas (2012), Jiang, Nelson, and Vytlacil (2014)). There
is a problem of incentives at the asset origination stage followed by a problem
of asymmetric information that may limit the ability to trade these assets (i.e.,
that reduces asset liquidity). This raises two questions: how should originators
be incentivized to screen asset quality while preserving liquidity in secondary
markets for these assets, and is there a need for policy intervention?
To address these questions, I develop a theoretical framework to study the
trade-off between an asset’s quality and liquidity. In the model, an originator
can exert costly effort to improve the quality of an asset, the cash flows of
which can be sold in secondary markets. The key feature of the model is that
both the level of the screening effort and the quality of the originated asset
are the originator’s private information. This setup aims to capture the fact
that not all of the information that is acquired while screening or monitoring
can be easily conveyed to outside investors.3Asset screening may therefore
expose the originator to illiquid secondary markets for the asset due to her
private information. This is costly when there are gains from trade with outside
investors. In this setting, I explore the resulting tension between productive
efficiency—the quality of originated assets—and allocative efficiency—the final
allocation of asset cash flows.
This framework is general and can be applied to many economic settings.
The premise is that an agent’s hidden action determines the distribution of
output and gives the agent superior information about the realization of this
output. This superior information can, in turn, affect the liquidity of claims
on this output. All originators of informationally sensitive financial assets face
this trade-off. This tension is also present in nonfinancial settings where an
agent, such as a venture capitalist (VC) or a CEO with stock options, can
exert effort to improve a firm’s cash flows. When monitoring generates private
information, too much monitoring may impact the liquidity of the agent’s stocks
(Faure-Grimaud and Gromb (2004)) or exit options (Aghion, Bolton, and Tirole
(2004)). Other examples include the relationship between firm control and its
impact on stock market trading (Coffee (1991), Bhide (1993), Dewatripont and
Tirole (1994), Maug (1998), Medrano and Vives (2004)).
2The 2010 report of the Financial Stability Board to G20 leaders stated “re-establishing secu-
ritization on a sound basis remains a priority in order to support provision of credit to the real
economy and improve banks’ access to funding” (FSB (2010)).
3See Qian, Strahan, and Yang (2015) for evidence on how incentives and communication costs
affect information production in banking.
The Downside of Asset Screening for Market Liquidity 1939
Turning back to the setting of interest here, the model has three periods
and features a manager and market investors. The manager can finance and
manage one risky project that pays off in the final period. In the first period,
she exerts costly effort to screen projects to increase the likelihood of finding
a “good” project. If a “good” project is found, it is financed; if not, an average
project from the pool of potential projects is financed. Both the screening effort
and the quality of the financed project are the manager’s private information.
In the intermediate period, the manager can exploit gains from trade with
investors, who are more patient, by selling securities that are backed by the
project’s cash flows. The cash flows that are not sold are retained by the man-
ager. In the first-best of this economy, the manager (i) chooses screening effort
in the first period such that the social marginal benefit of asset screening equals
its social marginal cost—full productive efficiency, and (ii) sells all of her asset
cash flows in the intermediate period to investors—full allocative efficiency.
Full productive and allocative efficiency cannot be achieved in the presence
of information frictions. I thus characterize the optimal mechanism that max-
imizes ex ante efficiency (second-best). I then describe the equilibrium alloca-
tions and study the conditions under which they differ from the second-best
allocations. Under the optimal mechanism, retention of cash flows is essential
to implement positive effort. Ex ante efficiency is maximized with differen-
tial retention levels—managers with poor-quality assets should not retain as
much as those with good-quality assets. In contrast, equilibrium allocations
can feature either too little or too much screening effort relative to the second-
best. While the presence of asymmetric information is essential to sustaining
the equilibrium with positive effort, too much effort may generate inefficiently
illiquid assets.
The predictions of the model shed light on the observed booms and busts in
origination and securitization of some asset classes around the 2008 to 2009
financial crisis. First, as gains from trade increase, which can be interpreted
as an increase in liquidity needs, trade in secondary markets increases while
the quality of underlying asset cash flows decreases. Second, when gains from
trade are large enough, investors’ beliefs about the manager’s screening effort
become self-fulfilling, which increases market fragility. A second equilibrium
with no asset screening and no cash flow retention arises. This behavior is in
line with the observed trend in the United States of certain securitized assets,
such as nonagency MBS, that featured a boom in the years leading up to the
crisis that was accompanied by a decrease in the quality of the underlying loans
(Mian and Sufi (2009)).
Under the optimal mechanism, while retention of cash flows is essential to
implement positive screening effort, it reduces gains from trade. As a result,
effort is optimally chosen to trade off the social benefit of asset screening with its
social cost, which includes the indirect cost of the cash flow retention required to
implement it. This indirect cost generates a wedge between the first-best and
the second-best allocations. The notion that cash flow retention incentivizes
asset screening is consistent with evidence in Ashcraft, Gooriah, and Kermani
(2014) that an increase in the amount of cash flow retention is correlated

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT