The Determinants of Long‐Term Corporate Debt Issuances

AuthorDOMINIQUE C. BADOER,CHRISTOPHER M. JAMES
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jofi.12264
Published date01 February 2016
Date01 February 2016
THE JOURNAL OF FINANCE VOL. LXXI, NO. 1 FEBRUARY 2016
The Determinants of Long-Term Corporate Debt
Issuances
DOMINIQUE C. BADOER and CHRISTOPHER M. JAMES
ABSTRACT
A significant proportion of the debt issued by investment-grade firms has maturities
greater than 20 years. In this paper we provide evidence that gap-filling behavior is
an important determinant of these very long-term issues. Using data on individual
corporate debt issues between 1987 and 2009, we find that gap-filling behavior is
more prominent in the very long end of the maturity spectrum where the required
risk capital makes arbitrage costly. In addition, changes in the supply of long-term
government bonds affect not just the choice of maturity but also the overall level of
corporate borrowing.
WHILE THE AVERAGE MATURITY of corporate borrowing is about five years, com-
panies sometimes issue very long-term bonds not tied to a particular tangible
asset. Perhaps the best known example is Walt Disney Company’s 100-year
(callable after 30 years) $300 million senior subordinated debenture issue in
1993 dubbed “Sleeping Beauty” bonds.1More recently, Apple issued $3 billion
in 30-year fixed rate bonds in 2013.2While 100-year bonds are rare, unse-
cured bond offerings with maturities of more than 20 years are common. For
example, between 1987 and 2009, 472 firms covered by Compustat made 1,620
unsecured bond offerings with maturities of more than 20 years and a total face
Dominique C. Badoer is at the University of Missouri and Christopher M. James is at the Uni-
versity of Florida. We thank two anonymous referees, Kenneth Singleton (Editor), David Brown,
Sarah Hamersma, Jonathan Hamilton, Joel Houston, Andy Naranjo, Michael Roberts, and seminar
participants at the Banking Conference at Universit`
a Bocconi, the IAES Conference (Montr´
eal),
and the University of Florida for helpful comments. The authors have read the Journal of Finance’s
disclosure policy and have no conflicts of interest to disclose.
1While the offering was well received, some analysts voiced concerns over the risk asso-
ciated with long-term issues. For example, William Gross of Piper Capital Management was
quoted as saying “It’s crazy, look at the path of Coney Island over the last fifty years and see
what happens to amusement parks” (Thomas T. Vogel, “Disney amazes investors with sale
of 100-year bonds” The Wall Street Journal, July 21, 1993, p.61). More recently, in mid-2010
several 100-year bonds were issued purportedly in response to very low long-term rates. See
http://www.bloomberg.com/news/2010–08–23/yield-hunt-driving-demand-for-longest-maturity-
debt-sales-credit-markets.html.
2The Wall Street Journal commented on Apple’soffering, stating “Thirty years ago, the internet
was in its infancy, the Macintosh didn’texist, and you might have purchased a handful of Porsche
944s for the cost of one gigabit worth of computer storage. Thirty years from today,it’s pretty much
impossible to project what the technology landscape will look like” (Rolfe Winkler, “Even Apple’s
crystal ball has clouds”, May 1, 2013, p. 46).
DOI: 10.1111/jofi.12264
457
458 The Journal of Finance R
value (in 2009 dollars) of $590 billion (the median maturity of these long-term
offerings was just over 30 years). Virtually all of these issuers were also active
in the short end of the maturity spectrum and regularly issued debt with ma-
turities of less than five years. As we outline below, very long-term unsecured
debt issues and significant year-to-year variation in the maturity of issues are
difficult to explain in the context of contracting cost theories of maturity choice
in which the average maturity of assets and the importance of growth options
drive debt maturity choice.3
In this paper we examine the determinants of long-term debt issues using
a data set of bond issues and bank borrowing by public firms during the 1987
through 2009 period. We address three related questions. First, to what extent
are very long-term corporate debt issues a response to changes in credit mar-
ket conditions, such as changes in the maturity composition of U.S. Treasury
debt or changes in the term structure of interest rates? Second, what types of
borrowers have the greatest supply elasticity with respect to changes in credit
market conditions? Third, to what extent do changes in the maturity compo-
sition of Treasury bonds and the term structure of interest rates affect the
propensity of firms to issue debt?
Our analysis is motivated by recent work by Greenwood, Hanson, and Stein
(2010, hereafter GHS) on “gap filling” and corporate debt maturity choice. GHS
develop a theory in which corporate issuers respond to shocks in the supply of
short- and long-term Treasury bonds. The basic idea is that important classes
of investors, such as pension funds and insurance companies, have a preference
for relatively safe long-term assets. Given a shock to the supply of long-term
government bonds, the cost and availability of risk capital limits the ability
of arbitrageurs to fill the gap. As a result, bond yields can stray from the
yields implied by the expectations hypothesis. Corporate issuers, particularly
those with investment-grade credit ratings, attempt to exploit differences in
the expected return on short- versus long-term bonds leading to supply shifts
in the long-term corporate market offsetting changes in the supply of long-term
government bonds.
We hypothesize that gap filling is likely to be a more important determinant
of very long-term corporate borrowing (20 years or more) than shorter-term
borrowing, for at least two reasons. First, the gap-filling hypothesis is based
on highly rated corporate issuers having a comparative cost advantage in ar-
bitraging rate differences arising from shifts in the maturity composition of
government debt. An important factor affecting the cost of arbitrage activity is
the amount of capital arbitrageurs must commit to a position and the amount
of capital available to them. Capital constraints include limits on leverage and
costs of raising external equity.4Given capital constraints, arbitrage costs are
likely to vary directly with the amount of risk capital needed. The amount of
3See, for example, Myers (1977), Barclay and Smith (1995), and Guedes and Opler (1996)for
discussions of agency cost explanations of maturity choice.
4See Gromb and Vayanos(2010) for a survey of the theoretical literature on financing constraints
and the limits of arbitrage.
Long-Term Corporate Debt Issuances 459
Tabl e I
Annual Implied Price Volatilities
This table presents the annual means of daily implied volatilities associated with the correspond-
ing futures on U.S. Treasury securities. Daily implied volatilities for the underlying securities are
calculated from a weighted average of the volatilities of the two closest call options. For all secu-
rities, the contract used is the closest pricing contract month that is expiring at least 20 business
days from the corresponding observation date. 20-year Treasury bond futures refer to U.S. Trea-
sury bonds that, if callable, are not callable for at least 15 years from the first day of the delivery
month or, if not callable, have a maturity of at least 15 years from the first day of the delivery
month. 10-year Treasury note futures refer to futures on notes maturing at least 6 1/2 years, but
not more than 10 years, from the first day of the delivery month. 5-year Treasury note futures refer
to U.S. T-notes that have an original maturity of not more than five years and three months and
a remaining maturity of not less than four years and two months as of the first day of the delivery
month. 2-year Treasury note futures refer to futures on U.S. Treasury notes that have an original
maturity of not more than five years and three months and a remaining maturity of not less than
one year and nine months from the first day of the delivery month but not more than two years
from the last day of the delivery month.
20-Year 10-Year 5-Year 2-Year
1994 10.42 7.45 4.95 1.94
1995 9.41 6.65 4.59 2.17
1996 9.98 6.75 4.72 2.03
1997 8.83 5.48 3.73 1.68
1998 8.66 5.71 4.09 2.06
1999 8.82 6.05 4.18 3.05
2000 9.32 6.52 4.13 1.60
2001 9.46 7.10 4.76 2.19
2002 10.98 7.93 5.47 2.15
2003 12.04 8.04 5.38 2.02
2004 10.01 6.92 4.70 1.87
2005 8.08 5.10 3.41 1.42
2006 6.79 4.25 2.86 1.26
2007 7.32 5.10 3.74 1.78
2008 13.5 9.22 6.68 3.00
2009 15.6 8.95 5.46 1.76
Total Average 9.97 6.71 4.56 1.97
N3,969
risk capital needed is likely to vary in turn with the price volatility associated
with a position. As shown in Table I, the average daily implied price volatility
of Treasury bonds increases with their maturity, with the implied price volatil-
ity associated with 20-year Treasury bonds averaging over five times the daily
price volatility of two-year bonds. Thus, for any value at risk (VAR) level the
amount of risk capital required for trades in very long-term Treasuries is orders
of magnitude larger than in the short end of the market.
The second reason we expect gap filling to be an important determinant of
long-term issues is that very long-term issues are difficult to explain in the
context of agency cost theories of maturity choice, which predict that issuers
will match the maturity of their liabilities to the maturity of their assets (see
Myers (1977)). In our sample, long-term issues (20+years) average 30 years

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT