The Credibility of Performance Feedback in Tournaments

DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jems.12086
Published date01 March 2015
Date01 March 2015
AuthorIván Marinovic
The Credibility of Performance Feedback in
Tournaments
IV´
AN MARINOVIC
Graduate School of Business
Stanford University
655 Knight Way
Stanford, CA 94305-7298
imvial@stanford.edu
This paper studies the effect of performance feedback on tournament outcomes, when a possibly
dishonest principal may manipulate the agents’ expectations to stimulate their effort. Under
plausible circumstances, an increase in the principal’s propensity to tell the truth (i.e., integrity)
induces a mean preserving spread in the distribution of effort and leads to a decrease in expected
profits and welfare. More generally, I identify conditions under which a lower integrity can
improve the effectiveness of financial incentives in inducing the agents’ effort, thus leading to
higher expected profits for the principal.
1. Introduction
Performance feedback policies are pervasive within firms. Ederer (2010) cites evidence
showing that between 74% and 89% of business organizations have a formal performance
feedback system. Law firms and consulting firms, where promotion is a crucial compo-
nent of the incentive package, inform workers about their previous performance and
promotion prospects long before the decisions are made. Yet, surveys reveal widespread
discontent with the way performance feedback is conducted in a substantial percentage
of U.S. and U.K. firms (Fletcher, 2001). Two of the most cited reasons for this discon-
tent are feedback manipulation by self-interested appraisers and the lack of meaningful
feedback provided by the process (Barlow, 1989).1
This paper studies the effects of performance feedback on tournament outcomes
when a potentially self-interested principal may manipulate the communication to stim-
ulate the agents’ effort. I build on the model of Ederer and Fehr (2007). At the outset, the
principal chooses the tournament reward. If the agents accept the offer and join the firm,
the principal privately observes a signal of the agents’ talents hence their relative like-
lihoods of promotion. Then the principal communicates this information to the agents
and based on this communication the agents exert effort.
Because the incentives of the principal and the agents are strongly misaligned, the
canonical cheap talk model (Crawford and Sobel, 1982) predicts that no information
transmission can ever take place: any communication should be mere babbling.Soto
I would like to thank Jeremy Bertomeu, Florian Ederer, Ilan Guttman, and Marco Ottaviani for very helpful
comments and Yinqing Xing and Sandro Ambuehl for great researchassistance.
1. For example, according to Jeffrey Pfeffer: “At North Carolina software company SAS Institute, David
Russo, then head of HR, got cheers from employees in the mid-1990s for a bonfire celebration that fed appraisal
forms into the flames. Nothing has changed much since then. Managers don’t like doing appraisals. Employees
don’t like getting them. Perhaps that’s because they all suspect what the evidence shows: such performance
reviews don’t work.”
C2015 Wiley Periodicals, Inc.
Journal of Economics & Management Strategy, Volume24, Number 1, Spring 2015, 165–188
166 Journal of Economics & Management Strategy
enable meaningful communication, I assume the principal has a positive (and known)
propensity to be truthful, which I call integrity. This definition of integrity captures not
only the principal’s moral characteristics, but more broadly the transparency of the firm’s
feedback process, or the amount of discretion available to the principal to manipulate
the communication. In that sense, integrity is viewed here as an observable metric of
transparency arising, for example, from the firm’s prior investments and commitments.
In the model, the tension arises from the agents being uncertain about whether
the principal is truthful, thus having to infer this from the communication itself. When
untruthful, the principal must choose the feedback carefully to avoid being detected, for
otherwise his ability to influence the agents’ effort would vanish.
I use this framework to study how integrity affects social welfare. I focus on the
case in which the agents’ participation constraints bind. Surprisingly, I find that under
plausible and rather general circumstances integrity has an adverse effect over the
principal’s expected profits and the social welfare. The mechanism behind this result is
intuitive. Given the tournament’s reward, the agents’ effort depends on their perception
of relative talent: the greater the perceived gap between the agents’ talents the less
competitive the tournament becomes. Naturally, the perception of a more competitive
environment induces higher effort levels. Hence, when untruthful, the principal would
like to persuade the agents that the tournament is highly competitive. However, the
agents are aware of the potential conflict of interest and they discount the feedback,
particularly if the principal has low integrity and claims high levels of competitiveness
in the tournament. In this context, a principal with higher integrity is more likely to
draw the agents’ beliefs about competitiveness to polar levels. A higher integrity thus
increases the dispersion of the agents’ conditional beliefs about the marginal return to
effort. This is the key to understanding why integrity may have an adverse effect on
social welfare.
For the sake of illustration, suppose the agents’ equilibrium effort strategy is linear
in conditional beliefs. By the law of iterated expectations, a higher integrity cannot affect
expected effort. However, it does increasethe volatility of effort. In turn, a more volatile
effort translates into a higher expected cost of effort: that is, the more volatile the effort
the higher the cost that the agents expect to bear in the tournament. This means that,
given the tournament’s reward, an increase in integrity lowers the agents’ expected
utility from participating in the tournament. In equilibrium, however,this adverse effect
of integrity must be borne by the principal as he must set the tournaments’ rewards so
as to ensure the agents’ participation.
The general analysis is more subtle because the effort strategy may not be linear
in conditional beliefs. Hence, integrity has the potential to affect both the mean and the
volatility of effort. The sign of the mean effect crucially depends on the convexity of the
marginal cost of effort. For difficult tasks, namely those exhibiting a convex marginal
cost of effort, the effort strategy is concave in conditional beliefs. The greater dispersion
of conditional beliefs induced by an increase in integrity results in lower expected
effort, lower expected profits, and lower expected welfare. By contrast, for simple tasks,
namely those exhibiting concave marginal cost of effort, the effort strategy is convex
in conditional beliefs. Hence the greater dispersion of conditional beliefs induced by
higher integrity leads not only to more volatile effort but also to greater expected effort.
A higher integrity is thus detrimental to the agents’ interests but may be beneficial to
those of the principal. In fact, consider the case where the agents’ participation constraint
does not bind, which happens, for instance, when the agents’ outside option is relatively
low but the agents are protected by limited liability. Given the tournament’s reward,

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT