The Cost of Capital for Alternative Investments

Published date01 October 2015
Date01 October 2015
AuthorERIK STAFFORD,JAKUB W. JUREK
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jofi.12269
THE JOURNAL OF FINANCE VOL. LXX, NO. 5 OCTOBER 2015
The Cost of Capital for Alternative Investments
JAKUB W. JUREK and ERIK STAFFORD
ABSTRACT
Traditional risk factor models indicate that hedge funds capture pre-fee alphas of 6%
to 10% per annum over the period from 1996 to 2012. At the same time, the hedge
fund return series is not reliably distinguishable from the returns of mechanical S&P
500 put-writing strategies. We show that the high excess returns to hedge funds and
put-writing are consistent with an equilibrium in which a small subset of investors
specialize in bearing downside market risks. Required rates of return in such an
equilibrium can dramatically exceed those suggested by traditional models, affecting
inference about the attractiveness of these investments.
LINEAR FACTOR REGRESSIONS (e.g., Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM), Fama–
French three-factor model, Fung–Hsieh nine-factor model, and conditional
variations thereof) indicate that hedge funds deliver statistically significant
alphas (Sharpe (1964), Lintner (1965), Fama and French (1993), Agarwal and
Naik (2004), Fung and Hsieh (2004), Hasanhodzic and Lo (2007)). Over the
period from January 1996 to June 2012, pre-fee alpha estimates for diversified
hedge fund indices range from 6% to 10% per annum, and thus, even after
deducting fees, investors appear to earn large abnormal returns relative to
commonly used risk models. These estimates indicate a degree of market inef-
ficiency, that is dramatically different from other areas of investment manage-
ment (Fama and French (2010)), and suggest that hedge fund returns cannot
be replicated by portfolios combining traditional risk factors. Another inter-
pretation of these results is that the proposed risk models fail to identify, or
accurately measure, an important dimension of risk that hedge fund investors
specialize in bearing. In this paper, we explore this explanation, focusing on
downside market risks and their implications for cost of capital computations
when the asset market equilibrium may involve investor specialization.
Jurek is at Bendheim Center for Finance, Princeton University and NBER. Stafford is at
Harvard Business School. We thank Joshua Coval, Ken French, Samuel Hanson, Campbell Har-
vey (Editor), Jonathan Lewellen, Andrew Lo (discussant), Burton Malkiel, Robert Merton, Gideon
Ozik (discussant), Andr´
e Perold, David Sraer, Jeremy Stein, Marti Subrahmanyam (discussant),
Jules van Binsbergen (discussant), Russell Wermers (discussant), and seminar participants at
Dartmouth College, Harvard Business School, Imperial College, Bocconi University, USI Lugano,
Princeton University, Spring 2013 Q-Group Seminar, 2013 CEAR Workshop on Institutional In-
vestors, the 2012 NBER Asset Pricing Summer Institute, the 2011 NYU Five-Star Conference, the
4th NYSE Liffe Hedge Fund Research Conference, and the BYU Red Rock Finance Conference for
helpful comments and discussions.
DOI: 10.1111/jofi.12269
2185
2186 The Journal of Finance R
Merton (1987) explores a simple one-factor equilibrium model in which
agents only trade subsets of assets, and demonstrates that linear factor pricing
fails in this setting. In particular, assets that are borne by specialized investors
appear to earn positive abnormal returns relative to the market portfolio.
Equivalently, the equilibrium required rate of the return on these “specialized
investments” exceeds the required rate of return implicit in linear factor
regressions. We argue that a similar type of equilibrium may help rationalize
the returns to alternative investments (and also index put-writing strategies).
In practice, while alternatives comprise a modest 2% share of the global
wealth portfolio, most investors hold none of these investments, leaving a few
investors with large allocations relative to the aggregate supply.1For example,
as of June 2010, 40% of the aggregated Ivy League endowment assets were
allocated to nontraditional assets (Lerner, Schoar, and Wang (2008)). From this
perspective, the high excess returns of alternatives may simply reflect fair com-
pensation demanded by specialized investors, rather than unearned returns,
or “alpha.”
We focus on the possibility that, in aggregate, hedge fund investors spe-
cialize in bearing downside market risks. These risks concentrate losses in
highly adverse economic states, and are known to receive high equilibrium
risk compensation. Importantly, the additional compensation demanded by in-
vestors that specialize in bearing these risks is likely to be large relative to
that prevailing in the absence of segmentation, as these assets magnify the
negative skewness of aggregate (market) shocks. While evidence of nonlinear
systematic risk exposures resembling those of index put-writing is provided by
Mitchell and Pulvino (2001) for risk arbitrage and Agarwal and Naik (2004)
for a large number of equity-oriented strategies, the literature—aside from Lo
(2001)—has been comparatively silent on nonlinear replicating strategies. We
fill this gap by constructing the returns to a range of S&P 500 equity index op-
tion writing strategies designed to satisfy exchange margin requirements, as
emphasized by Santa-Clara and Saretto (2009).2Specifically, we contrast the
hedge fund index returns with two put-writing portfolios with different down-
side risk exposures, as measured by how far the put option is out-of-the-money
and how much leverage is applied to the portfolio. Each of these strategies
provides an unbiased proxy for pre-fee hedge fund returns, delivering a zero
1As of the end of 2010, the total assets under management held by hedge funds stood at roughly
$2 trillion (source: HFRI), in comparison to a combined global equity market capitalization of $57
trillion (source: World Federation of Exchanges) and a combined global bond market capitalization
of $54 trillion, excluding the value of government bonds (source: TheCityUK, “Bond Markets 2011”).
2Our methodology for constructing put-writing strategy returns improves on several nonlinear
risk factors proposed in the hedge fund literature. For example, we consider a wide range of option
moneyness levels and leverage magnitudes, whereas Agarwal and Naik (2004) only use options
that are 1% out-of-the-money. Fung and Hsieh (2004) construct factors based on the theoretical
returns to lookback straddle portfolios, that are designed to capture long exposure to volatility.
Instead, our focus is on strategies that are short volatility. The extreme volatility of the lookback
straddle factors also suggests that—in order to ensure feasibility—short exposures would place
severe margin requirements on the investor.
The Cost of Capital for Alternative Investments 2187
Jan96 Dec99 Dec03 Dec07 Dec11
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
Feasible Linear Replicating Portfolio
Actual
CAPM
Fama−French
Fung−Hsieh
Jan96 Dec99 Dec03 Dec07 Dec11
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
Feasible Nonlinear Replicating Portfolio
Actual
Put Writing [Z = −1, L =2]
Put Writing [Z = −2, L = 4]
Jan96 Dec99 Dec03 Dec07 Dec11
−0.35
−0.3
−0.25
−0.2
−0.15
−0.1
−0.05
0
Drawdown
Actual
CAPM
Fama−French
Fung−Hsieh
Jan96 Dec99 Dec03 Dec07 Dec11
−0.35
−0.3
−0.25
−0.2
−0.15
−0.1
−0.05
0
Drawdown
Actual
Put Writing [Z = −1, L = 2]
Put Writing [Z = −2, L = 4]
Jan96 Dec99 Dec03 Dec07 Dec11
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
Infeasible Linear Replicating Portfolio
Actual
CAPM
Fama−French
Fung−Hsieh
Jan96 Dec99 Dec03 Dec07 Dec11
−0.35
−0.3
−0.25
−0.2
−0.15
−0.1
−0.05
0
Drawdown
Actual
CAPM
Fama−French
Fung−Hsieh
Figure 1. Replicating the risks and returns of the HFRI Fund Weighted Composite In-
dex. The top panels plot the cumulative value of $1 invested in the HFRI Fund WeightedComposite
Index (pre-fees; “Actual”), along with various replicating strategies. The left-hand panel shows the
cumulative return based on the fitted values from three common factor models (CAPM, Fama–
French/Carhart, Fung–Hsieh) exclusive of the estimated intercept (feasible linear replication).
The middle panel repeats the plot based on the fitted factor models, but returns are cumulated
inclusive of the estimated intercept (infeasible linear replication). The right-hand panel plots the
returns to the two put-writing strategies (feasible nonlinear replication). Relative to the [Z=−1,
L=2] put-writing strategy, the [Z=−2, L=4] strategy applies a higher amount of leverage
to options that are written further out of the money. The bottom panels plot the corresponding
monthly drawdown series for the hedge fund index and the replicating strategies.
intercept and unit slope coefficient when the index excess returns are regressed
onto the strategy excess returns.
Figure 1plots the value of $1 invested in the aggregate hedge fund index
(pre-fees), along with various replicating strategies. The left-hand panel shows
the cumulative return based on the fitted values from three common factor
models exclusive of the estimated intercept (feasible linear replications), the
middle panel repeats the plot but inclusive of the estimated intercept (infea-
sible linear replication), and the right-hand panel plots the returns to the two
put-writing strategies (feasible nonlinear replication). The performance of the
aggregate hedge fund index is impressive, accumulating wealth much more
quickly than the risk-matched common factors predict would be fair. Popular
common factor models explain most of the time series variation, but miss most
of the mean, identifying this as alpha. The graph also shows that the com-
mon factors beyond the market factor explain little of the overall pattern, so
much of our analysis emphasizes the market factor. On the other hand, simple

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT