The Collision of Indeterminate Environments and Porter’s Forces: Uncertainty Fields and Their Impact on Entrepreneurial Alertness

DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1002/jsc.2058
AuthorDavid Guggenheim
Published date01 May 2016
Date01 May 2016
RESEARCH ARTICLE
Strat. Change 25: 239–257 (2016)
Published online in Wiley Online Library
(wileyonlinelibrary.com) DOI: 10.1002/jsc.2058
Copyright © 2016 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd.
Strategic Change: Briengs in Entrepreneurial Finance
Strategic Change
DOI: 10.1002/jsc.2058
The Collision of Indeterminate Environments and
Porter’s Forces: Uncertainty Fields and Their Impact
on Entrepreneurial Alertness1
David Guggenheim
Department of Management, Southern Illinois University, Carbondale, IL, USA
In order to identify new product/market opportunities, the elds of entrepreneurship
and strategy are brought closer together with a reconceptualization of Porter’s
forces as data‐driven components of market and industry uncertainty.
Opportunity recognition for entrepreneurs operating with prior market or indus-
try knowledge, or the ‘discovery context’ (Alvarez and Barney, 2007), requires
decision‐making that may incorporate rational risk assessments for those oppor-
tunities that exist in the fabric of a well‐understood product market. ese weak-
nesses or discontinuities represent market imperfections (Shane and Venkataraman,
2000) whose recognition and evaluation may be enhanced through the acquisition
and analysis of objective data in a manner similar to that of nonentrepreneurial
managers (Busenitz, 1996). is process should shift the notion of entrepreneurial
opportunity recognition, or ‘alertness,’ from a cognitive frame weighted toward
subjective perception (e.g., Ardichvili, Cardozo, and Ray, 2003) to a more mecha-
nistic set of data analytic processes (omas, Clark, and Gioia, 1993). Even with
a focus on the psychological processes underpinning entrepreneurial alertness,
Gaglio and Katz (2001) recognized the importance of objective‐leaning market
process schemas in opportunity recognition. Objective opportunity identication
is particularly cogent in the topic of incremental innovation (Gatignon et al.,
2002), which may be conceptualized as calculable risk within the discovery context
of entrepreneurship.
ese attempts at strictly logical decision processes are asymptotic in nature
in that one may only approach rationality due to boundaries established by the
gap between information requirements and information availability, the cost of
obtaining missing information, the time needed for optimal decision‐making, and
cognitive limitations of the human mind (Simon, 1957). Coincident with this
recognition of ‘bounded rationality’ was the appearance of environmental uncer-
tainty as a key component enforcing the restrictions on rational decision behaviors
1 J.E.L. classication code: L1.
Advances in data collection and
analysis may serve to reduce the
role that prior knowledge of a
market or industry plays in
opportunity recognition, but the
question remains as to what data
to collect and how to analyze it.
While environmental uncertainty
has been theorized as an
important component in
opportunity identication,
strategic management education
has expounded on industrial
economics as a means to detect
weaknesses or discontinuities in
existing markets.
The objective environmental
uncertainty can be merged with
Porter’s Forces to create
‘uncertainty elds,’ mathematical
constructs from which algorithms
may be devised to detect
exploitable market imperfections.
240 David Guggenheim
Copyright © 2016 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strategic Change
DOI: 10.1002/jsc
(March and Simon, 1958; Cyert and March, 1963). Envi-
ronmental uncertainty is composed of two parts: dimen-
sions of the environment and vectors and rates of change
for those dimensions. Simon originally conceived of it to
be economic in origin, consisting of demand and cost
uncertainty (Simon, 1957), but many researchers have
since added to this construct (Duncan, 1972; Downey
et al., 1975; Miller and Friesen, 1982; Dess and Beard,
1984; Milliken, 1987; Keats and Hitt, 1988; Jaworski and
Kohli, 1993).
McMullen and Shepherd (2006) theorized the impor-
tance of uncertainty in opportunity recognition and they
identied a ‘noteworthy’ construct that embodied aspects
of bounded rationality (Milliken, 1987). However, the
Milliken uncertainty construct has found limited applica-
tion as a set of objective markers (e.g., Miller and Shamsie,
1999) largely because of context sensitivity; after all, there
is but a single industry that may use the number of
Academy Awards won as a proxy for organizational eect
uncertainty! Moreover from a practical perspective, this
selection of state, eect, and response uncertainty, while a
valuable contribution to risk management through the
lens of multilevel analysis, subtly reinforced the asserted
importance of prior domain knowledge in entrepreneurial
actions (Shane and Venkataraman, 2000; Ardichvili et al.,
2003; Grégoire, Barr, and Shepherd, 2010) to keep it
within the perceptual abilities of nonscientist entrepre-
neurs. However, restricting the relationship between entre-
preneurs and their associated production processes by
industrial silos may not be entirely necessary for the forma-
tion of new ventures and the development of incremental
economic opportunities in existing product markets.
Subjective perceptions of environmental uncertainty
have been found valuable for navigating an existing market
or industry (i.e., after the opportunity has been actual-
ized) as long as they draw a close parallel to authentic
volatility (Bourgeois, 1985), but the processes surround-
ing new market identication and selection, or the oppor-
tunity recognition phase, may require a grounding in
objective data (Bourgeois, 1980). is is particularly
important for those who are on the outside looking in,
thus seeking to break the compartmentalization enforced
by prior domain knowledge constraints. Objective mea-
sures for environmental uncertainty, while lacking the
multilevel features of the Milliken (1987) prototype, oer
greater scope and simpler computation in their applica-
tion (e.g., Keats and Hitt, 1988).
Yet, while scholars have acknowledged the importance
of understanding environmental uncertainty in both the-
oretical and practical arenas, it would appear that graduate
business programs have yet to embrace its widespread use
in the curricula devoted to opportunistic analysis (Navarro,
2008; Rubin and Dierdor, 2009). With this deciency,
how is the manager‐as‐entrepreneur to detect embryonic
opportunity in existing markets? Instead of inculcating an
appreciation for the analysis of environmental uncertainty,
MBA programs ll this gap by mandating the use of
Porter’s Five Forces toward analyzing competitive environ-
ments (Porter, 1980, 2008). e macroeconomics of
supplier power, customer power,2 threat of new entrants,
competitive rivalry, and the threat of substitutes is often
cited but less well understood in developing actionable
decisions from constructive measures, in part because of
aggregated product markets (i.e., industries) and blurred
interaction eects (see Figure 1).
Grundy (2006) recognized certain limitations of Por-
ter’s model, specically the lack of knowledge about inter-
force relationships, a static versus dynamic perspective of
those constructs and relationships, and gaps in under-
standing those forces as elds instead of singular points
within product markets. Compounding the interpretation
of these forces is an inherent weakness related to discrimi-
nant validity that becomes evident at the algebraic level.
In other words, Porter’s Forces overlap one another, thus
making it dicult to discriminate as to which force is
2 Porter’s original work specied buyer power but because the
target collection of rms are also buyers, we have changed
this to customer power for clarity. In this way, the industry is
modeled as a supply chain (Flynn, Huo, and Zhao, 2010)
instead of isolated bilateral relationships.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT