Structuring and Governing Alliances: New Directions for Research

AuthorJeffrey J. Reuer,Farok J. Contractor
Published date01 November 2014
Date01 November 2014
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1002/gsj.1082
STRUCTURING AND GOVERNING ALLIANCES:
NEW DIRECTIONS FOR RESEARCH
FAROK J. CONTRACTOR1and JEFFREY J. REUER2*
1School of Business, Rutgers University, Newark, New Jersey, U.S.A.
2Krannert School of Management, Purdue University, West Lafayette,
Indiana, U.S.A.
The purpose of this article is to identify a future research agenda relating to the structure and
governance of international alliances. Despite emerging research that is being carried out on
topics related to the structuring, management, and governance of domestic and international
collaborations, much remains unknown and warrants future work. The new directions in
alliance research partially stem from the recent greater availability of databases that contain
actual contract details. We also relate some of the contributions of the articles in the special
issue to the research agenda we are calling for. Copyright © 2014 Strategic Management
Society.
INTRODUCTION
The new direction for alliance research lies in the
analysis of agreement details as they relate to the
structuring, governance, and functioning of collabo-
rations. For too long, the field has been restricted to
overly broad categories of collaborations such as
‘equity versus non-equity’ or ‘relational versus con-
tractual’ without actually probing the details,
anatomy, or agreement structure of the alliance. In
part this was because agreement specifics were not
easily available, and many popular databases like
Securities Data Company (SDC) reported only
sketchy summaries of alliances, based on public
announcements, without agreement details. With
such publicly available data, conducting alliance
research was akin to practicing medicine without
dissection. Moreover, such databases used to capture
only a fraction of the actual number of collabora-
tions formed (Schilling, 2009). Today, scholars are
carrying out primary data collection and using richer
data from secondary sources that have information
on actual agreements, including Thomson Reuters’
Recap and the U.K.’s Pharmaprojects.
The strategic drivers for interfirm cooperation,
manifested in a variety of alliance arrangements
including equity joint ventures (JVs), are well
known and fall into four broad categories of motives:
(1) market growth or revenue enhancement as a con-
sequence of the cooperation; (2) efficiency or cost
reduction; (3) sharing or reducing risk; and (4)
access to knowledge or learning.1That alliances are
often temporary arrangements that can terminate
because the views of the partners will diverge over
time—in part due to bounds on rationality and the
lack of predictability of the future environment the
alliance will encounter (Williamson, 1981)—is also
Keywords: alliance governance; contracts; international joint
ventures
*Correspondence to: Jeffrey J. Reuer, Krannert School of Man-
agement, Purdue University, West Lafayette, IN 47907-2056,
U.S.A. E-mail: jreuer@purdue.edu
1Early work such as Contractor and Lorange (1988) focused on
the strategic rationales for forming alliances. Scholars later also
began to focus on the relational aspects (e.g., Dyer and Singh,
1998) and trust (e.g., Das and Teng, 1998). Attention began to
turn to contract details more recently, as exemplified in Poppo
and Zenger (2002) and Reuer and Ariño (2007).
Global Strategy Journal
Global Strat. J., 4: 241–256 (2014)
Published online in Wiley Online Library (wileyonlinelibrary.com). DOI: 10.1002/gsj.1082
Copyright © 2014 Strategic Management Society
received academic wisdom. Nevertheless, when
forming an alliance, negotiators almost inevitably
conclude an agreement between the prospective
partners, keeping in mind the ‘shadow of the future’
or future contingencies, to the extent they can be
envisaged (Parkhe, 1993). The fact is that virtually
all alliances—including equity JVs—have a legally
drawn up agreement that governs the future relation-
ship and activities of the joint operation. Academic
studies focusing on trust (e.g., Das and Teng, 1998),
or treating ‘relational alliances,’ or using secondary
data sources that summarize announcements of JVs
with no mention of side agreements between the JV
partners, should not lead scholars to conclude that
alliances formed with joint capital investments or
memoranda of understanding alone are common-
place. Hence, it has been surprising that, until a few
years ago, scant academic attention had been paid to
the details of agreements as they relate to the post-
formation governance of the alliance and the
exchanges between the partners.
Recent work such as Reuer and Ariño (2007),
Ryall and Sampson (2009), Adegbesan and Higgins
(2010), Lumineau and Malhotra (2011), and Ariño
et al. (2014) has begun to specifically examine con-
tract provisions in greater detail. These provisions
include criteria for the post-formation governance of
the alliance, such as which partner will make which
types of decisions (Lerner and Merges, 1998).
Studies have examined finer details in agreements
such as contingency planning clauses (Argyres,
Bercovitz, and Mayer, 2007), procedures for deci-
sion making and the resolution of disagreements,
and the appointment of key personnel (Robinson and
Stuart, 2007; Ryall and Sampson, 2009). Certain
safeguards, controls, and monitoring clauses exist in
most alliance contracts (Faems et al., 2008). Coor-
dination mechanisms (Lumineau and Malhotra,
2011) or mandatory information sharing and disclo-
sure are specified in the alliance contract to forestall
disagreements (Palay, 1984).As the essence of many
alliances is the distribution of tasks between the part-
ners, this is often specified ex ante. Call options exist
in both equity as well as non-equity alliances. The
contract can specify triggers, or thresholds, that give
one party the right to buy a certain number of its
partner’s shares in a JV or the right to acquire exclu-
sively for itself the intellectual property (IP) rights or
technology developed by the other partner (or
jointly) (e.g., Ziedonis, 2007). Termination clauses
of many varieties occur in agreements whereby one
of the allies can wind up their partnership. These
detailed alliance design parameters considered in
recent research are in sharp contrast to the large
literature examining trends and motives for collabo-
rations, discrete governance choices firms make
(e.g., equity versus non-equity alliance decisions),
and the usage of coarse indicators of control, moni-
toring, and incentives (e.g., equity stakes in JVs).
Alliance governance complexity
In the broadest sense, what determines the gover-
nance of an alliance, expressed in the level of detail,
complexity, and length of alliance agreements?
Moreover, what contract clauses are appropriate for
different types of alliances? Broadly, this depends on
four factors:
(1) the purview and mission of the alliance;
(2) deal-specific variables, or considerations
intrinsic to the collaboration, such as the nature
of the knowledge shared (Contractor and Ra,
2002), size of assets at stake and asset speci-
ficity, as well as agreement provisions;
(3) relational skills or alliance experience of the
parties involved (Mayer and Argyres, 2004;
Ryall and Sampson, 2009); and
(4) environmental variables that include institu-
tional, market, and country considerations such
as the level of IP protection, intensity of com-
petition, and market and political uncertainty
(Oxley, 1999).
Purview and mission of the alliance
The rubric ‘alliances’ necessarily includes a diverse
set of cooperative activities that varysubstantially by
mission or task, by their degree of consequence to
one or both allies, by size of investment (both finan-
cial and managerial), by the level of partner interac-
tions once the alliance is in progress, and by the level
of risk. Figure 1 gives merely examples of alliance
types and is not intended as a hard and fast catego-
rization or as exhaustive.At one end of the spectrum,
a transfer of patent or IP rights between two phar-
maceutical companies need not involve a very
detailed agreement, especially if there is a lump-sum
or one-time payment in cash or reciprocal rights
(e.g., Hagedoorn and Hesen, 2007). The ex post
interaction between the parties, commitment, and
risk (apart from the opportunity cost on the part of a
seller who misjudges the potential of the IP trans-
ferred, or buyer’s remorse) can be low.
242 F. J. Contractor and J. J. Reuer
Copyright © 2014 Strategic Management Society Global Strat. J., 4: 241–256 (2014)
DOI: 10.1002/gsj.1082

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT