Strategic and Natural Risk in Entrepreneurship: An Experimental Study

AuthorDana Sisak,John Morgan,Martin Sefton,Henrik Orzen
Date01 April 2016
Published date01 April 2016
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jems.12140
Strategic and Natural Risk in Entrepreneurship:
An Experimental Study
JOHN MORGAN
Haas School of Business and Department of Economics
University of California, Berkeley
California, United States
morgan@haas.berkeley.edu
HENRIK ORZEN
Department of Economics
University of Mannheim
Mannheim, Germany
MARTIN SEFTON
School of Economics
The University of Nottingham
Nottingham, United Kingdom
DANA SISAK
Erasmus School of Economics & Tinbergen Institute
Erasmus University Rotterdam
The Netherlands
We report on the results of experiments where participants choose between entrepreneurship
and an outside option. Entrepreneurs enter a market and then make investment decisions to
capture value. Payoffs depend on both strategic risk (i.e., the investments of other entrepreneurs)
and natural risk (i.e., luck). Absent natural risk, participants endogenously sort themselves
into entrepreneurial and safe types, and returns from the two paths converge. Adding natural
risk fundamentally changes these conclusions: Here we observe excessive entry and excessive
investment so that entrepreneurs earn systematically less than the outside option. These payoff
differences persist even after many repetitions of the task. With a risky outside option, entry
further increases and about one-third of entrepreneurs adopt a passive strategy,investing little or
nothing. Finally, we examine an environment where an individual must become an entrepreneur
but chooses the stakes over which she will compete. Due to under-entry and under-investment in
the high stakes setting, the returns gap grows to over 15 percentage points. A two-factor model
incorporating loss aversion and love of winning can rationalize these returns patterns.
We thank Amy Nguyen-Chyung, participants at the 2009 Amsterdam Symposium on Behavioral and Ex-
perimental Economics, the 2009 winter meetings of the Economic Science Association, the 2010 Bay Area
Experimental Economics Conference, and the University of East Anglia for helpful comments and sugges-
tions. This paper substantially benefited from helpful referee comments. Weare indebted to Elke Renner for
kindly sharing her data on risk attitudes at the University of Nottingham. Financial support from the National
Science Foundation and the Swiss National Science Foundation is gratefully acknowledged. Sefton thanks the
ESRC (ES/K002201/1) for support.
The copyright line for this article was changed on July 13, 2016 after original online publication.
This is an open access article under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial License,
which permits use, distribution and reproductionin any medium, provided the original work is properly cited
and is not used for commercial purposes.
C2015 The Authors. Journal of Economics & Management Strategy Published by Wiley Periodicals, Inc.
Journal of Economics & Management Strategy, Volume25, Number 2, Summer 2016, 420–454
Risk in Entrepreneurship 421
1. Introduction
Many view entrepreneurship as a fundamental driver of economic growth. As a
result, countries routinely subsidize entrepreneurship, especially small-scale ventures.
An important determinant of entrepreneurial activity and performance are the risks
entrepreneurs face. Thus, much of the entrepreneurship literature seeks to identify
characteristics, such as risk preferences, as well as personality traits of would-be
entrepreneurs.1Wu and Knott (2006) point out that, although entrepreneurs are
conventionally risk-averse in responding to demand uncertainty, they are risk-seeking
(overconfident) about risks related to their own ability. In this paper, we distinguish
between two aspects of risk: Strategic risk is the risk associated with the fact that payoffs
are affected by the actions of other entrepreneurs and success or failure depends not
only on one’s own entrepreneurial decisions, but also on the entrepreneurial decisions
of others. It is more difficult to succeed, and entrepreneurial returns are likely to be
lower, in crowded markets where competitors invest heavily. Natural risk recognizes
that entrepreneurial decisions alone do not determine financial outcomes. Luck also
plays a crucial role. Certainly, any aspiring entrepreneur opening up a new restaurant
or coffee shop realizes the role that fads, fashions, and other vicissitudes of fortune
have on outcomes. We study the impact of these different types of risk on entry into
entrepreneurship and subsequent performance.
Controlling for differences in strategic versus natural risk as well as the levels and
riskiness of a would-be entrepreneur’s outside option is difficult using field data. Thus,
we use laboratory experiments to examine how these factors influence entrepreneurship.
This has the advantage that we can control for these aspects of the market precisely. It
also lets us compare rates of return between entrepreneurship and an outside option
including how these returns vary over time. Finally, we also examine the life-cycle of
entrepreneurship decisions, that is, how experience affects both entry and investment
in entrepreneurial activity.
As far as we are aware, our study is one of the first to investigate different types
of entrepreneurial risks using the methodology of laboratory experiments. We do this
by examining choices to enter a competitive environment, where we manipulate the
risks associated with entering or not.2Although we refer to entrants as “entrepreneurs”
throughout the paper, this is merely a metaphor for the situations that we sought to
approximate via experiments. We labeled choices neutrally when presenting them to
subjects, and we cannot know if a subject had in mind the role of entrepreneur. We
could equally well have labeled an entrant as a “contestant” because our entrepreneur-
ship game is mathematically equivalent to a Tullock contest. Previousexperiments have
examined isolated aspects of the entrepreneur’s choice. For example there is an extant
experimental literature on the decision to enter the market in the first place. In the stan-
dard entry experiment, individuals simultaneously decide whether or not to enter and
payoffs are determined according to a schedule such that entry payoffs are decreas-
ing in the number of entrants. Equilibrium, which is in mixed strategies, suggests that
1. See, for example, Parker (2009) who offers a survey as well as Caliendo and Kritikos (2012) for an
overview of recent developments in this literature.
2. Camerer and Lovallo (1999) also study entry into a tournament-like setting, but do not manipulate
risks. Several experiments have used a similar competitive environment to us (Tullockcontests, Tullock, 1980),
and manipulate the riskiness of the contest, but do not examine entry decisions (e.g., Chowdhury et al., 2014;
Masiliunas et al., 2012; Fallucchi et al., 2013; Shupp et al., 2013). Wesummarize these findings on p. 6. See also
Bohnet et al. (2008), as well as Eckel and Wilson (2004), for comparisons of strategic and natural risk in trust
settings.
422 Journal of Economics & Management Strategy
entry will occur up to the point where the expected profits of each entrant are equal
to the value of the outside option. The main finding in this literature is that theory
models of entry perform well in characterizing behavior. Indeed, Nobel Laureate Daniel
Kahneman famously quipped that theory worked like “magic” in predicting behavior
in these games.3Subsequent studies have found slight tendencies toward excess entry
when equilibrium predicts few entrants and under-entry when equilibrium predicts
many entrants (see Camerer, 2003, for a review). Even so, the fundamental prediction
of competitive equilibrium—payoff equalization of entrants relative to the second best
alternative—continues to acquit itself nicely.
The central contribution of our paper is to study entry decisions in contexts that
more closely mimic those faced by entrepreneurs. Specifically, we modify the standard
entry game as follows: Subjects make real-time entry decisions where they observe the
number of entrants currently in the market. In our view, this is a closer match to the
reality of entry than the usual model where entry decisions aremade simultaneously and
where the key difficulty is to overcome the coordination problem. Following the entry
decision, entrants participate in a Tullock (lottery) contest in which they simultaneously
make investments in their businesses. Larger relative investments produce a greater
expected share of the profits in the industry; however success is by no means guaranteed.
In some treatments, luck plays a key role—here a single winner is determined where
the probability of winning is proportional to the relative investments made. In contrast,
in our Shares treatment, the link between payoffs and investment is more direct. Each
entrant enjoys a fraction of industry profits in proportion to their investments.
We also vary the nature of the outside option. We conduct treatments where the
outside option is deterministic. But in practice the alternative to not entering a market
may be inherently risky. Indeed, often the second best use of an entrepreneur’s time and
talent is undertaking another, different startup. To capture these differences, we also re-
port the results of treatments wheret he payofffrom the outside option is stochastic (Coin
Flip treatment) and where the outside option represents an alternative entrepreneurial
opportunity with different stakes (Dual treatment).
Together, our treatments shed light on the role of strategic versus natural risk
on entry decisions and post-entry performance. They also allow for a more nuanced
view of the fundamental prediction of competitive equilibrium—the equalization of the
value of inside and outside options—when outside options have both environmental
and strategic risk as well. Our experiments are designed to come closer in bridging the
gap between the simple and elegant theory of equilibrium entry with the messy reality
of real world entry decisions.
We begin by reproducing the results from standard entry experiments (Baseline
treatment). Consistent with earlier studies, we observe payoff equalization between
entrepreneurship and the fixed outside option in a setting where “entrepreneurship”
merely amounts to entering a market and where each entrepreneur earns a fixed payoff
which is declining in the number of entrants. Moreover, specialization naturally arises:
some individuals repeatedly choose the entrepreneurship path whereas others follow a
different path and select the outside option.
Our main findings are:
In the Baseline experiment, entrepreneurs’ return on investment converges to
the outside option from below.This conclusion is unaltered with the addition
of strategic risk. When entrepreneurship involves natural risk as well, its return
3. Kahneman (1988).

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT