Stock Market Returns and Consumption

Date01 December 2020
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jofi.12968
AuthorMARCO DI MAGGIO,AMIR KERMANI,KAVEH MAJLESI
Published date01 December 2020
THE JOURNAL OF FINANCE VOL. LXXV, NO. 6 DECEMBER 2020
Stock Market Returns and Consumption
MARCO DI MAGGIO, AMIR KERMANI, and KAVEH MAJLESI
ABSTRACT
This paper employs Swedish data on households’ stock holdings to investigate how
consumption responds to changes in stock market returns. We instrument the actual
capital gains and dividend payments with past portfolio weights. Unrealized capital
gains lead to a marginal propensity to consume of 23% for the bottom 50% of the
wealth distribution and about 3% for the top 30% of the wealth distribution. House-
hold consumption is significantly more responsive to dividend payouts across all parts
of the wealth distribution. Our findings are consistent with households treating cap-
ital gains and dividends as separate sources of income.
IN THE UNITED STATES,STOCKHOLDINGS REPRESENT the largest share of fi-
nancial assets on households’ balance sheets, reaching more than $32 trillion
(with about $15 trillion in nonretirement accounts), which makes them com-
parable in importance to the stock of housing wealth. Given their prominence,
movements in stock prices and dividend payments might significantly affect
households’ consumption and savings decisions. With soaring stock prices,
households’ savings rate is at a 12-year low, which raises the question of
Marco Di Maggio is with Harvard Business School and NBER. Amir Kermani is with UC
Berkeley and NBER. Kaveh Majlesi is with Lund University, Monash University, CEPR, IFN,
and IZA. The data used in this paper come from the Swedish Interdisciplinary Panel (SIP) ad-
ministered at the Centre for Economic Demography, Lund University, Sweden. We thank two
anonymous referees, an Associate Editor,and the Editor, Stefan Nagel, for helpful comments that
significantly improved the paper. We also thank Malcolm Baker; James Cloyne; Chris Carroll;
Francesco D’Acunto; Samuel Hartzmark; Luigi Guiso; Matti Keloharju; Ralph Koijen; David Laib-
son; Geng Li; Jonathan Parker; Luigi Pistaferri; Larry Schmidt; Paolo Sodini; David Sraer; Stijn
Van Nieuwerburgh; Gianluca Violante; Roine Vestman; Annette Vissing-Jørgensen; and seminar
participants at the 2017 meeting of the Econometric Society, New York University Conference on
Household Finance, CEPR Household Finance Workshop in Copenhagen, Helsinki Finance Sum-
mit, NBER SI Consumption Micro to Macro, MIT Sloan, UCSD, CREI and UPF, NY Fed, UC
Berkeley, University of Zurich, SFS Cavalcade, the European Finance Association, and the West-
ern Finance Association for helpful comments. We thank TerranceOdean for providing data from
a large brokerage in the United States. Leonel Drukker and Erik Grenestam provided excellent
research assistance. Kermani is grateful for research support from the Fisher center for Real Es-
tate and Urban Economics and Majlesi acknowledges research support from Jan Wallanders and
Tom Hedelius Foundation. Aside from these funding sources, all three authors have nothing to
disclose with respect to The Journal of Finance disclosure policy.
Correspondence: Amir Kermani, Haas School of Business, UC Berkeley 2220 Piedmont ave,
Berkeley,CA 94720 510-664-4132; e-mail: kermani@berkeley.edu.
DOI: 10.1111/jofi.12968
© 2020 the American Finance Association
3175
3176 The Journal of Finance®
whether stock market trends do indeed drive households’ spending habits.1
This shift away from saving, however, could leave some consumers exposed to
changes in market conditions. Furthermore, concerns about the consumption-
wealth effects of stock market returns have been the main driver of U.S.
monetary policy sensitivity to stock price movements (Cieslak and Vissing-
Jørgensen (2020)). A natural question that arises is thus how much of a decline
in aggregate consumption should we expect if stock prices take a sudden turn
for the worse as they did during past recessions?
Despite the central importance of these questions, the literature lacks a com-
prehensive study on the causal impact of changes in stock market wealth on
households’ consumption. This is due to several challenges. First, aggregate
movements in stock prices are endogenous with respect to other macroeco-
nomic shocks, such as expectations of future income growth and consumer
confidence (Beaudry and Portier (2006)). Second, due to home bias, exploit-
ing regional cross-sectional variation to control for macroeconomic fluctuations
is also not ideal. One could potentially address these challenges by exploit-
ing household-level data such as the Consumer Expenditure Survey (CEX),
but the advantages of using such data are counterbalanced by the lack of ac-
curacy in the reported measures of capital gains (Dynan and Maki (2001)).2
Furthermore, households bias their investments toward their own companies
and local industries, resulting in correlations between capital gains and other
factors that directly affect their income, which may introduce a new source
of endogeneity that is absent in the aggregate data (Benartzi (2001), Coval
and Moskowitz (2001), Mitchell and Utkus (2003), Meulbroek (2005)). Finally,
given the skewness of stockholdings, it is important to estimate the consump-
tion behavior of households at the top of the wealth distribution, which are
usually underrepresented in surveys.3
In this paper, we overcome these challenges by using highly granular
household-level data from Sweden. Due to the presence of a wealth tax, we
are able to obtain a full picture of households’ balance sheets at the end of
each year from 1999 to 2007, when the tax was repealed. We have data on
the universe of households’ portfolio holdings at the security level, as well as
information about their debt obligations and real estate transactions. To mea-
sure consumption, we follow the residual approach proposed by Koijen, Van
Nieuwerburgh, and Vestman (2015) and impute consumption as a residual
of households’ disposable income net of other transactions, and we validate
1The Commerce Department has reported that the savings rate was 2.4% of disposable house-
hold income in December 2017, the lowest rate since September 2005. The savings rate had risen
to 6.6% when the recession ended in June 2009.
2There is no direct measure of capital gain in the CEX, and capital gains are imputed based on
changes in total security holdings and the amount of sales and purchases during that year. Any
such imputation requires strong assumptions on the timing and portfolio rebalancing of house-
holds. Moreover, many households report zero capital gains in years in which the stock market
performs remarkably well.
3See Table A.1 for the distribution of stock holdings in the United States according to the
Survey of Consumer Finances.
Stock Market Returns and Consumption 3177
this measure against survey information. Koijen, Van Nieuwerburgh, and
Vestman (2015), Eika, Mogstad, and Vestad (2020), and Kolsrud, Landais, and
Spinnewijn (2019) discuss the quality of this imputed measure of consumption
based on administrative data and their comparison with survey data. These
papers show that the quality of the consumption measure based on the residual
method depends on the availability of detailed household-level asset allocation
data as well as data on housing transactions.
Even with such data, households’ portfolio choices are endogenous and might
be driven by omitted factors that also drive their consumption behavior. We
address this issue in several ways. First, we exploit the panel nature of our
data and estimate all of our regressions using first differences. This allows us
to capture time-invariant differences across households that might be corre-
lated with the level of their capital gains or dividend income. Second, we limit
the heterogeneity across households’ portfolios by estimating the marginal
propensity to consumer (MPC) separately for different parts of the wealth dis-
tribution. Third, we also exclude stockholdings in households’ own industry
from their portfolios before computing capital gains and dividends. This en-
sures that our results are driven by households’ holdings in industries other
than their own, as fluctuations in such industries are less likely to be corre-
lated with changes in households’ income.
One might still be concerned that changes in capital gains and dividend in-
come could be driven by dynamic changes in households’ portfolios. Indeed,
changes in households’ portfolios may be driven by factors such as the liquida-
tion of stock holdings due to an expenditure shock or a large durable purchase,
the very same factors that are likely responsible for household consumption.
We therefore implement a simulated IV strategy where we instrument the
variations in capital gains and dividend income with the capital gains and div-
idend income that would have accrued had the household kept its portfolio the
same as observed in previous years. Intuitively, the portfolio weights in previ-
ous years should not be determined by future shocks that drive both stock re-
turns and consumption choices. In other words, our identification comes from
the stickiness in households’ portfolios, for which we find strong evidence in
our data.
Our first main result is that the MPC out of (unrealized) capital gains for
households in the top 30% of the financial wealth distribution is about 3% and
does not exhibit significant variation between, for instance, households in the
70th to 90th percentile and households in the top 5% of the wealth distribu-
tion. In contrast, the MPC for households in the bottom half of the distribution
is significantly higher at about 23%. However, it is worth noting that these
households own less than 7% of overall stockholdings. Our estimates are ro-
bust to directly controlling for realized capital gains, which we observe for a
subsample. Intuitively, households can freely respond to changes in unrealized
capital gains by adjusting their savings decisions.4In further tests, we also
4Note that this is also why transaction costs, related to the liquidation of stock holdings, are
unlikely to drive the difference between the MPC for capital gains and dividends.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT