Spatial Price Discrimination in the Spokes Model

Published date01 September 2014
AuthorCarlo Reggiani
Date01 September 2014
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jems.12066
Spatial Price Discrimination in the Spokes Model
CARLO REGGIANI
School of Social Sciences
University of Manchester
Manchester M13 9PL
carlo.reggiani@manchester.ac.uk
The spokes model allows to address nonlocalized spatial competition between firms. In a spatial
context, firms can price discriminate using location-contingent pricing. Nonlocalized competition
implies that neighboring effects are not relevant to firms. This paper analyzes spatial price
discrimination and location choices in the spokes model. Highly asymmetric location patterns are
one outcome if the number of firms is sufficiently high: in that case, one firm supplies a generally
appealing product whereas others focus on a specific niche. Moreover, multiple equilibria arise for
intermediate values of the number of firms. In this case, the location patterns do not always globally
minimize the sum of transport costs: asymmetric configurations distribute more efficiently the
cost between firms.
1. Introduction
Price discrimination is a pervasive practice in many markets: it takes place both in
highly concentrated markets and in more competitive ones, in which several firms are
active. Price discrimination also arises in markets strongly characterized by a spatial
dimension. A feature of these markets is that competition is not necessarily localized:
firms compete to attract a consumer not only with neighboring firms but also with more
distant ones. A number of spatial nonlocalized markets exist where price discrimination
takes place; moreover, if location is interpreted as the space of characteristics, examples
include alcoholic and soft drinks, shoes and clothing, software, and many others: in all
these markets, IT and marketing innovation are leading to wider and more personalized
product lines as firms try to better match consumers’ tastes and extract surplus from
consumers in different segments.
A key strategic decision in these markets is firms’ location and, hence, which
segment of the market to be targeted. A very relevant question is whether firms hit on a
specific niche of the market or adapt their product line in a way that makes it appealing
to a wider segment of consumers, that is, they supply a “general purpose” product line.
The spokes model (Chen and Riordan, 2007a) provides a framework to analyze
markets characterized by spatial but nonlocalized competition between firms: the model
extends the Hotelling (1929) approach to the case of several segments and an arbitrary
number of firms by modeling the market as a collection of spokes with a common core.
Consumers can buy from whichever firm they like: if the firm is not located on their
own spoke, however, either the customer or the delivering firm have to travel through
the center of the market. The spokes model is an important alternative to the circular
I thank Hemant Bhargava, Anindya Bhattacharya, Bipasa Datta, Norman Ireland,Mario Pezzino, Mark Lijesen
Peter Simmons, Klaus Zauner, and specially Ramon Caminal; seminar and conference participants in York,
Manchester,Lecce, and Ljubljana; the editors and the anonymous referees for helpful comments and discussion.
The usual disclaimer applies.
C2014 Wiley Periodicals, Inc.
Journal of Economics & Management Strategy, Volume23, Number 3, Fall 2014, 628–649
Spatial Price Discrimination in the Spokes Model 629
city model (Salop, 1979) when the neighboring effects of competition are not particularly
relevant.
This paper addresses the question of what segments of the market firms target by
analyzing optimal location in the spokes model. The analysis shows that, in presence
of price discrimination/product personalization, the equilibrium outcome can be char-
acterized by one firm whose product line is appealing to consumers in all segments of
the market; the remaining competitors target only part of their own market segment,
focusing on a niche of customers with a strong preference for the products supplied by
the firm. In devising the optimal location/product line patterns in the spokes model
with price discrimination, it is also found that multiple equilibria arise depending on
the number of firms in the market. An interesting finding is that, in that case, one of the
outcomes may not globally minimize the sum of transportation costs.
The spokes model has been introduced relatively recently but has already been
widely adopted. Chen and Riordan (2007a) show that the model captures Chamberlin’s
original idea of monopolistic competition; moreover,strategic interaction between firms
may lead to price increasing competition. Caminal and Claici (2007) use the model to
show how the business stealing effect makes loyalty-rewardingschemes mostly procom-
petitive. Chen and Riordan (2007b) illustrate the joint relevance of vertical integration
and exclusive dealing in foreclosing the upstream market and increasing downstream
prices. Germano (2009) and Germano and Meier (2013) adopt the model to address issues
related to the bias of information in media markets. Caminal (2010) analyzes the supply
of content in different languages in bilingual contexts. Caminal and Granero (2012) look
at the provision of variety by multiproduct firms in the spokes model. Mantovani and
Ruiz-Aliseda (2011) analyze cooperative innovation activity of firms producing com-
plementary products. A unifying characteristic of the recalled literature is the focus on
pricing and entry aspects of the interaction between firms. This paper is, to the best of
my knowledge, the first to address the issue of location in the spokes model.
The contribution of this paper is also related to the literature on spatial price dis-
crimination and endogenous location choice. Thisse and Vives (1988) observed that price
discrimination in a spatial market is detrimental to firms’ profits: firms exploit their in-
formation on consumers’ locations and can match any offer made by a rival firm, unless
this is lower than the cost of delivering the good. The classical paper of Lerner and
Singer (1937) established that the optimal location configuration on a line is transport
cost minimizing. Lederer and Hurter (1986) analyze endogenous location and establish
the existence of price-location equilibria in a rather general (e.g., two-dimensional prod-
uct space, generic consumers’ distribution) spatial duopoly. Their results confirm that
the profit maximizing locations chosen by firms correspond to the ones that minimize
the overall transport costs afforded by firms. However, in presence of multiple equi-
libria, the location configuration may not be globally minimizing the sum of transport
costs. MacLeod et al. (1988) consider the price-location equilibria of an n-firms spa-
tial model where the number of firms is endogenously determined by the fixed costs.
Free entry might lead to either a too large or a too small number of varieties. Vogel
(2011) analyzes spatial price discrimination and the location of heterogeneous firms in
the circle finding that more efficient firms are relatively more isolated in equilibrium.
Anderson and De Palma (1988) question Lederer and Hurter’s results by introducing
product heterogeneity: the equilibrium location pattern minimizes the overall transport
costs only in presence of homogeneous or very heterogeneous products. Konrad (2000)
shows that in presence of a contest for consumers, in which firms afford sunk costs, the
equilibrium locations are not minimizing overall transport costs. Finally, Gupta (1992)

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT