Single-Firm Conduct

Pages269-378
269
CHAPTER V
SINGLE-FIRM CONDUCT
A. Fundamentals
1. Introduction and Overview
Many of the leading public and private antitrust cases in the
technology sector have involved single-firm conduct challenged under
Section 2 of the Sherman Act. Notable examples include cases against
IBM, Microsoft, Intel, and others. More recently, the Federal Trade
Commission (FTC) has invoked its powers under Section 5 of the FTC
Act to bring and settle single-firm conduct cases against technology
firms, including high-profile settlements with Intel and Google. In
addition, antitrust and competition regimes continue to expand
throughout the world. Like U.S. law, these regimes typically proscribe
certain categories of single-firm conduct deemed “abuse of dominance,”
as it is termed by those countries following the EU model, such as China.
2. United States
a. Sherman Act Section 2
Section 2 makes it unlawful to “monopolize, or attempt to
monopolize, or combine or conspire with any other person or persons, to
monopolize any part of the trade or commerce among the several States,
or with foreign nations.”1 A Section 2 monopolization claim has two
basic elements: “(1) the possession of monopoly power in the relevant
market, and (2) the willful acquisition or maintenance of that power as
distinguished from growth or development as a consequence of a
superior product, business acumen, or historic accident.”2 The mere
possession of monopoly power is not unlawful, unless accompanied by
1. 15 U.S.C. § 2 (2012).
2. United States v. Grinnell Corp., 384 U.S. 563, 570-71 (1966).
270 Handbook on Antitrust in Technology Industries
the additional element of exclusionary conduct.3 A claim of attempted
monopolization has three elements: “(1) that the defendant has engaged
in predatory or anticompetitive conduct with (2) a specific intent to
monopolize and (3) a dangerous probability of achieving monopoly
power.”4
The first element of a Section 2 monopolization claim, the
“possession of monopoly power in the relevant market,”5 requires only
that monopoly power exist, not that it be exercised.6 In the United States,
a single actor’s market share of 65 percent to 70 percent in a cognizable
relevant market generally constitutes compelling evidence of monopoly
power.7 In recent U.S. enforcement actions, the defendants have
substantially exceeded this baseline thresholdfor example, Microsoft
had a 95 percent share of an alleged relevant market,8 Intel had 80
percent,9 Rambus had 90 percent,10 and Qualcomm had 90 percent.11
3. Verizon Commc’ns v. Law Offices of Curtis V. Trinko, LLP, 540 U.S.
398, 407 (2004) (asserting that “mere possession of monopoly power, and
the concomitant charging of monopoly prices, is not only not unlawful; it
is an important element of the free-market system,”and in order to
“safeguard the incentive to innovate, the possession of monopoly power
will not be found unlawful unless it is accompanied by an element of
anticompetitive conduct”).
4. Spectrum Sports v. McQuillan, 506 U.S. 447, 455-456 (1993).
5. Grinnell Corp. 384 U.S. at 570. Monopoly power has been traditionally
defined as “the power to control prices or exclude competition,” United
States v. E.I. DuPont de Nemours & Co., 351 U.S. 377, 319 (1956), often
manifesting as the ability of a monopolist to “raise prices substantially
above competitive levels” without a corresponding decrease in demand,
United States v. Microsoft Corp., 253 F.3d 34, 51 (D.C. Cir. 2001).
6. Microsoft Corp., 253 F.3d at 51.
7. See, e.g., Spirit Airlines v. Nw. Airlines, 431 F.3d 917, 935-36 (6th Cir.
2005) (finder of fact can find monopoly power based on evidence of 70-
89 percent market share); Image Technical Servs. v. Eastman Kodak Co.,
125 F.3d 1195, 1206 (9th Cir. 1997) (“Courts generally require a 65
percent market share to establish a prima facie case of market power.”).
By contrast, as discussed below, a market share that permits an inference
of monopoly power is lower in China, Japan, and the European Union.
8. See Microsoft Corp., 253 F.3d at 51.
9. Complaint at 7, Intel Corp., FTC File No. 061-0247 (2010), available at
http://www.ftc.gov/sites/default/files/documents/cases/091216
intelcmpt.pdf.
10. See Rambus Inc. v. FTC, 522 F.3d 456, 459 (D.C. Cir. 2008).
Single-Firm Conduct 271
However, while a dominant share can provide an inference of monopoly
power, it is a rebuttable inference.12 Courts examine the degree to which
firms can maintain monopoly power by considering factors such as
whether competitors face barriers to expansion or entry.13
Attempted monopolization requires proof that the defendant had a
“specific intent to destroy competition or build monopoly.”14 Intent can
be shown through direct evidence or inferred from evidence of
anticompetitive conduct.15
An attempted monopolization claim requires a showing of a
dangerous probability of success in achieving monopoly power, which
may be based on the market structures.16 The existence of barriers to
entry can be powerful circumstantial evidence supporting the required
“dangerous probability” of success in an attempted monopolization
claim.17 Barriers to entry were a crucial factor in FTC v. Intel18 (a Section
5 claim), where the FTC identified four barriers to entry in concluding
that Intel’s 80 percent market share constituted market power:
“(1) product development; (2) the cost and expertise to develop
manufacturing capabilities; (3) intellectual property rights; [and]
(4) establishment of product reputation and compatibility.”19 The
11. See Broadcom Corp. v. Qualcomm Inc., 501 F.3d 297, 304 (3d Cir.
2007).
12. See Ball Mem’l Hosp. v. Mut. Hosp. Ins., 784 F.2d 1325, 1336 (7th Cir.
1986) (“Market share reflects current sales, but today’s sales do not
always indicate power over sales and price tomorrow.”).
13. See id. at 1335 (“In other cases . . . a firm’s share of current sales does not
reflect an ability to reduce the toal output in the market and therefore it
does not convey power over price. Other firms may be able . . . to divert
production into the market from outside.”).
14. Times-Picayune Publ’g Co. v. United States, 345 U.S. 594, 626 (1953).
15. See E.I. du Pont de Nemours & Co. v. Kolon Indus., 637 F.3d 435, 453
(4th Cir. 2011).
16. See Spectrum Sports v. McQuillan, 506 U.S. 447, 456 (1993).
17. See id. at 455-456; Barr Labs., Inc. v. Abbott Labs., 978 F.2d 98, 112 (3d
Cir. 1992); International Distr. Centers, Inc. v. Walsh Trucking Co., Inc.,
812 F.2d 786, 792 (2d Cir. 1987).
18. Complaint at 13, Intel Corp., FTC File No. 061-0247 (2010), available at
http://www.ftc.gov/sites/default/files/documents/cases/091216
intelcmpt.pdf.
19. Id. at 7.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT