Horizontal Restraints

Pages45-139
45
CHAPTER II
HORIZONTAL RESTRAINTS
Horizontal restraints or agreements are those among competitors or
potential competitors. They raise particular antitrust concerns because of
their inherent potential to eliminate or limit competition. Yet technology
markets have multiple characteristics that encourage procompetitive
horizontal arrangements.
A key characteristic of modern technology markets (especially in
software, computer hardware, electronics, and telecommunications) is
that a product’s value often depends, to varying degrees, on its
interoperability with other firms’ products. A second characteristic is the
constant and rapid development of next-generation technology and the
associated short life cycle of many products. Those two characteristics
give rise to a third: to speed development, competitors often develop new
products for their own and adjacent markets through joint ventures,
collaborations, and less formal types of “coopetition” with competitors.
The Antitrust Guidelines for Collaboration Among Competitors
(Competitor Collaboration Guidelines) issued by the Department of
Justice (DOJ) and Federal Trade Commission (FTC) highlight this
potential procompetitive benefit1 of competitor collaborations in
technology markets.2
1. See U.S. DEPT OF JUSTICE & FED. TRADE COMM N, ANTITRUST
GUIDELINES FOR COLLABORATIONS AMONG COMPETITORS § 1.1 (2000)
[hereinafter COMPETITOR COLLABORATION GUIDELINE S], available at
www.ftc.gov/sites/default/files/documents/public_events/joint-venture-
hearings-antitrust-guidelines-collaboration-among-competitors/ftcdo j
guidelines-2.pdf (defining procompetitiv e benefit as an “agreement’s
favorable competitive consequences, without taking account of its
anticompetitive harm”).
2. See id. § 2.3 (competitor collaborations may result in more efficient
exploitation of technol ogy that benefits “consumers through the reduction
of costs and the introduction of new products”). This Handbook is not
limited to technology markets as defined in the DOJ and FTC’s Antitrust
Guidelines for the Licensing of Intellectual Property. See U.S. DEPT OF
46 Handbook on Antitrust in Technology Industries
Courts have not created separate rules for horizontal arrangements
between technology firms, nor carved out technology exceptions from
traditional antitrust principles. But courts have recognized the
procompetitive benefits of collaborations among competitors in
technology markets, and have therefore generally analyzed them under
the rule of reason which weighs their anticompetitive effects (if any)
against their procompetitive effects.3
This chapter discusses horizontal agreements that may give rise to
antitrust concerns in technology industries, including agreements
controlling or affecting the price of products, agreements in the
formation or operation of joint ventures, agreements setting industry
standards, non-competition agreements, agreements involving
intellectual-property (IP) rights (such as patent-pooling agreements and
cross-licensing patents), agreements dividing markets, and concerted
refusals to deal and boycotts.4 Discussion of merger and acquisition
agreements will be left to Chapter 4.
JUSTICE & FED. TR ADE COMMN, ANTITRUST GUIDELINES FOR THE
LICENSING OF INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY § 3.2.2 (2017) [hereinafter 2017
IP GUIDELINES], available at https://www.justice.gov/atr/IPguidelines/
download (defining technology markets as consisting of “the intellectual
property that is licensed . . . and its close substitutesthat is, the
technologies or goods that are close enough substitutes significantly to
constrain significantly the exercise of market power with respect to the
intellectual property that is licensed”).
3. See Princo Corp. v. ITC, 616 F.3d 1318, 1334-35 (Fed. Cir. 2010) (en
banc) (noting that “resear ch joint ventures . . . ca n have significant
procompetitive features, and it is now well settled that an agreement
among joint venturers to pool their research efforts is analyzed under the
rule of reason” (citing Addamax Corp. v. Open Software Found., 152
F.3d 48, 52 (1st Cir. 1998))).
4. Another area of growing concern to worldwide enforcement agencies that
has not yet percolated through the courts in relation to horizontal
restraints is the importance to competition of access to “big data”the
aggregation of large amounts of d ata to support machine lear ning and the
use of algorithms to offer new and different products or set prices. See
FED. TRADE COMMN, BIG DATA: A TOOL FOR INCLUSION OR EXCLUSION
(2016), avaialable at https://www.ftc.gov/system/files/documents/reports/
big-data-tool-inclusion-or-exclusion-understanding-issues/160106big-
data-rpt.pdf; Margrethe Vestager, Competition Comm’r, EC, Big Data
Horizontal Restraints 47
A. Fundamentals
1. What Is a Horizontal Agreement?
Section 1 of the Sherman Act prohibits “[e]very contract,
combination . . . or conspiracy, in restraint of trade.”5 Courts have
interpreted this language to prohibit anticompetitive agreements among
competitors.6 Generally, competitors are defined as firms that operate at
the same level in a given market. The Competitor Collaboration
Guidelines highlight that competitors “encompasses both actual and
potential competitors.”7 In technology industries, it can be difficult to
determine who is a competitor versus who is instead vertically aligned,
much less a potential competitor. Non-public research & development
(R&D) and leapfrog product development only complicate the issues.
and Competition, Remarks to the EDPS-BEUS Conference on Big Data
in Brussels, Belgium (Sept. 29, 2016), available at https://ec.europa.eu/
commission/commissioners/2014-2019/vestager/announcements/big-
data-and-competition_en; see also COMPETITION COMM., DIRECTORATE
FOR FINANC IAL & ENTE R. AFFAIRS, OECD, ALGORITHMS AND
COLLUSION BACKGROUOND NOTE BY THE SECRATARIAT (June 9, 2017),
available at https://one.oecd.org/document/DAF/COMP(2017)4/en/pdf
(“[T]his paper focuses on the question of whether [big data ] algorithms
can make tacit collusion easier not only in oligopolistic markets, but also
in markets which do not manifest the structural features that are usually
associated with the risk of collusion”).
5. 15 U.S.C. §1 (2012).
6. Section 1 also addresses anticompetitive agreements among non-
competitors, which are addressed in Chapter 3 on vertical agreements.
See United States v. Apple, Inc., 791 F.3d 290 (2d Cir. 2015) (finding a
non-competitor, vertical participant liable for its role in orchestrating an
anticompetitive horizontal agreement among book publishers), cert.
denied, 136 S. Ct. 1376 (2016).
7. COMPETITOR COLLABORATION GUIDELINES, su pra note 1, § 1.1 n.6 (“A
firm will be considered a potential competitor if there is evidence that
entry by that firm is reasonably probable in the absence of the relevant
agreement, or that competitively significant decisions by actual
competitors are constrained by concerns that anticompetitive conduct
likely would induce the firm to enter.”).

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT