Should Firms Employ Personalized Pricing?

Published date01 October 2015
AuthorNoriaki Matsushima,Toshihiro Matsumura
Date01 October 2015
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jems.12109
Should Firms Employ Personalized Pricing?
TOSHIHIRO MATSUMURA
Institute of Social Science
the University of Tokyo
Hongo 7-3-1, Bunkyo, Tokyo 113-0033 Japan
matsumur@iss.u-tokyo.ac.jp
NORIAKI MATSUSHIMA
Institute of Social and Economic Research
Osaka University
Mihogaoka 6-1, Ibaraki, Osaka 567-0047 Japan
nmatsush@iser.osaka-u.ac.jp
This paper theoretically considers a duopoly model in which all firms do not always employ per-
sonalized pricing. Our model incorporates the fact that firms engage in marginal cost-reducing
activities after they decide whether to employ personalized pricing. When the ex ante cost differ-
ence between the firms is large, the less-efficient firm does not employ personalized pricing even
when the fixed cost to do so is zero. This is because employing personalized pricing induces the
rival firm to engage more in reducing its costs, which is more likely to harm the less-efficient firm.
1. Introduction
Recent developments in information technology (IT) have enabled firms to employ per-
sonalized pricing (Arora et al., 2008 and references therein). In the U.K. supermarket
industry, Tesco learns a variety of facts on customer purchasing activities using profiles
developed based on information collected through loyalty cards. Tescouses these data to
send personalized coupons and other offers to all Tesco Clubcardhouseholds quarterly,
and this is a huge operation that accounts for over 6% of the annual postal volume in the
United Kingdom (Raju and Zhang, 2010, pp. 131–132). 1However, some retailers do not
employ such personalized pricing strategies despite being able to. Asda, one of the “big
three” supermarkets in the United Kingdom, introduced a loyalty card scheme in 1994,
which it discontinued in 1999 after Tesco and Sainsbury, the other two largest chains, re-
spectively,launched their loyalty card programs in 1995 and 1996 (Thanassoulis, 2009).2
This raises the following question: Should all firms employ personalized pricing? If not,
why not? The purpose of this paper is to provide a simple rationale behind why firms
do not always employ personalized pricing.
We thank the Editor-in-Chief, an anonymous co-editor, and two anonymous referees for their helpful and
insightful comments. We also thank seminar participants at Nagoya University and Shinshu University for
their helpful comments. The authors gratefully acknowledge financial support from Grant-in-Aid from JSPS
KAKENHI Grant Numbers 22530175, 23330099, and 24530248. Needless to say, we are responsible for any
remaining errors.
1. Recently, grocers such as Safeway and Kroger have also begun using various methods to determine
individualized prices (The New YorkTimes [August 10, 2012]). Hoping to improve razor-thin profit margins,
they are creating specific offers and prices based on shoppers’ behaviors, which could encourage shoppers to
spend more.
2. The head of research and pricing at Asda mentioned that it preferredto provide customer value in other
ways (Rohwedder, 2006).
C2015 Wiley Periodicals, Inc.
Journal of Economics & Management Strategy, Volume24, Number 4, Winter 2015, 887–903
888 Journal of Economics & Management Strategy
The model setting is as follows. Two firms compete in a differentiated product
market, and each firm determines whether to employ personalized pricing. If a firm
employs personalized pricing, it is able to distinguish among customers and offer them
personalized prices; otherwise, it offers a standard nondiscriminatory price to all cus-
tomers. The model setting is based on the models of Thisse and Vives (1988) and Shaffer
and Zhang (2002). Our model also incorporates the fact that firms engage in marginal
cost-reducing or quality-improving activities.3More concretely, we set a model in which
the firms engage in these activities after determining their pricing policies. This assump-
tion implies that introducing personalized pricing is time-consuming because it requires
significant time to optimize, and thus, is a long-term decision.4
We explain the plausibility of the timing structure employed in this paper, that is,
firms determine their pricing policies before they engage in cost-reducing or quality-
improving activities. In the retailing context, retailers must construct electronic devices
to distribute appropriate promotional coupons using frequent-shopper programs based
on household purchase record analysis. Furthermore, to use such devices, these retailers
need to employ various items, including new cash registers, computers to gather cus-
tomer purchase records, applications for record analysis, data analysts, and customer
service offices for their frequent shopper programs.5After they set up personalized pric-
ing through these efforts, they engage in several cost-reducing activities. Tesco uses the
Clubcard information to determine which items should be stocked in a store given local
demographic and shopping habits (Thanassoulis, 2009); this reduces unnecessary stocks
of goods and lost sales opportunities. Clearly,Tesco engages in this efficiency-improving
effort by using the database after it does complex data mining, which is an expensive
intelligence source and a challenging process because of the enormous amount of data
generated (Hair Jr., 2007; Humby et al., 2007).6In other words, Tesco engaged in cost-
reducing activities after it invested in its customer data analysis by creating its loyalty
program. Moreover,as mentioned in Pancras and Sudhir (2007), in several research areas
including marketing, information systems, and computer science, research has focused
on the method by which firms should use individual browsing/purchasing data to
personalize advertising or promotions after introducing devices for personalized pro-
motions. This implies that employing personalized pricing requires significant effort to
implement promotions and has a long-term and time-consuming investment nature. We
therefore believe that the timing structure in our model is plausible.7
3. In our model, quality improvement is qualitatively equivalent with cost reduction, and is discussed in
Section 4.1.
4. This case is related to oligopoly models with cost reductions where firms engage in cost-reducing
activities before they set their prices or quantities. These models have been intensively discussed in the
literature of industrial organization (e.g., Brander and Spencer,1983). Recently, researchers have investigated
the relationship between firm asymmetry and R&D activities as discussed in this paper (Cohen and Klepper,
1996; Matsumura and Matsushima, 2010; Ishida et al., 2011). We believe that our paper can offer a novel
contribution in this context. Although most studies in this field have focused on the effects of R&D on
equilibrium pricing levels, our paper sheds light on the effect of each firm’s decision on pricing policy (i.e.,
whether to employ personalized pricing) on the strategic R&D behavior of firms, and the influence of the
degree of firm asymmetry.
5. In fact, Tesco calculated that a 1.6% uplift in sales was requiredto offset the 10 million pounds launch
cost of Clubcard and the cost of issuing membership cards and reward vouchers (Humby et al., 2007, p. 64).
6. In 2006, Tesco signed up 12 million Britons for its Clubcardprogram (Rohwedder, 2006).
7. Of course, even if a firm does not employ personalized pricing, it still engages in cost-reducing activity.
For instance, firms (retailers) incur investment costs to achieve saving in distribution costs through reduction
of the lead time, reduction of out-of-stock losses, and less falloff and damages. One might think that a firm
may seem to be able to keep its research and development (R&D) costs low by not employing personalized
pricing. Although we discuss the case in which the effort costs under the two pricing policies are the same in

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT