Selective Hearing: Physician‐Ownership and Physicians’ Response to New Evidence

Date01 February 2017
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jems.12178
AuthorJason Hockenberry,David H. Howard,Guy David
Published date01 February 2017
Selective Hearing: Physician-Ownership
and Physicians’ Response to New Evidence
DAVID H. HOWARD
Department of Health Policy and Management
Department of Economics
Emory University
Atlanta, GA
david.howard@emory.edu
GUY DAVID
The Wharton School
University of Pennyslvania
Philadelphia, PA
gdavid2@wharton.upenn.edu
JASON HOCKENBERRY
Department of Health Policy and Management
Department of Economics
Emory University
Atlanta, GA
jason.hockenberry@emory.edu
Physicians, acting in their role as experts, are often faced with situations where they must
trade off personal and patient welfare. Physicians’ incentives vary based on the organizational
environment in which they practice. We use the publication of a major clinical trial, which found
that a common knee operation does not improve outcomes for patients with osteoarthritis, as
an “informational shock” to gauge the impact of physicians’ agency relationships on treatment
decisions. Using a 100% sample of procedures in Florida from 1998 to 2010, we find that
publication of the trial reduced procedure volume, but the magnitude of the decline was smaller
in physician-owned surgery centers. Incentives affected physicians’ reactions to evidence.
1. Introduction
Vertical integration between physicians and others types of health care providers can
facilitate care coordination but, under the prevailing fee-for-service reimbursement
regime, may present physicians with incentives to referpatients for costly care. Physician
ownership arrangements are of special concern. Historically, physicians owned the of-
fices in which they provided primary care and basic exams but maintained arms-length
relationships with hospitals, imaging centers, surgery centers, and other facilities. Be-
ginning in the 1990s and continuing throughout the 2000s, many physicians assumed
ownership stakes in nonoffice facilities. Based on concerns that ownership encourages
physicians to recommend high-cost, low-value services, the U.S. Department of Health
and Human Services restricts physician ownership of health care facilities. Some types
of physician ownership arrangements are prohibited outright. Others are permitted as
long as they adhere to a number of regulatory “safe harbors.”
C2016 Wiley Periodicals, Inc.
Journal of Economics & Management Strategy, Volume26, Number 1, Spring 2017, 152–168
Selective Hearing 153
Research on physician ownership of surgery centers (Hollenbeck et al., 2010;
Hollingsworth et al., 2010a, b 2011; Mitchell, 2010), cardiac hospitals (Barro et al., 2006;
Mitchell, 2005, 2008; Nallamothu et al., 2007), imaging centers (Baker 2010; Shreibati and
Baker, 2011), and pharmacy services (Iizuka, 2007, 2012) has generally confirmed the
hypothesis that ownership is associated with increased use of health care services. A
limitation of most of these studies is that in the absence of a benchmark for the optimal
level of use, it is impossible to assess the impact of alternative practice arrangements on
consumer welfare. Physicians in physician-owned facilities provide more care, but we
do not know if they provide too much.
In 2002, the New England Journal of Medicine published the results of a trial (hereafter,
the “Moseley trial”) showing that arthroscopic surgery for patients with osteoarthritis
of the knee, a widely used procedure at the time, does not improve patient outcomes
(Moseley et al., 2002). Physicians perform arthroscopic surgery in hospital-based surgery
centers or freestanding centers, most of which are physician-owned. We use the trial as
an “informational shock” to compare physicians’ treatment decisions in hospital-based
and physician-owned ambulatory surgery centers. Wefind that the Moseley trial affected
practice patterns, but the magnitude of the effect was smaller in freestanding centers. The
Moseley trial identified a clinical scenario where physicians’ financial interests and the
interests of their patients diverge. Faced with the same set of scientific facts, physicians
in hospital-based and freestanding surgery centers responded differently.
2. Physician Ownership and Treatment Incentives
For every surgery, insurers pay a professional services fee to the surgeon for their labor
and a facility fee (or “technical” fee) to the hospital or surgery center to cover the cost of
supplies, nonphysician labor, and capital. Physician-owners split the profits generated
from facility fees based on their ownership shares, providing an extra incentive to
induce demand.1(It would be illegal under federal anti-kickback laws for a facility to
pay a physician based on the profits generated from directly from his own surgeries.)
Physician-owned facilities can also incentivize physicians by tying ownership shares
to productivity. Reallocating ownership shares on a predetermined schedule based on
each owner’s procedure volume is illegal. However, reallocating shares during times of
transition—when owners bring in a new partner or when an existing partner retires—is
legal as long as shares are exchanged at fair market value.
Managers in physician-owned facilities may be better than managers in other
types of facilities at eliciting high levels of physician effort (and inducement). Hospitals
are large, bureaucratic, multiproduct firms. The residual claimants (e.g., shareholders,
nonclinical administrators) are far-removedfrom the delivery of care. By contrast, groups
of surgeon-owners face stronger incentives to monitor each other’s case volumes, face
lower monitoring costs, and have greater ability to reward high-volume surgeons and
punish shirkers.
3. Clinical Background
Arthroscopic surgery is a minimally invasive procedure to treat damage to the soft
tissue of the knee. A patient undergoing arthroscopic surgery receives several small
1. Income effectsmay offset the direct incentives presented by ownership. If ownership increases physi-
cians’ income, they may reduce labor supply and/or efforts to induce demand (McGuire, 2000).

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT