Selection, Heterogeneity, and Entry in Professional Markets

DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jems.12074
Published date01 December 2014
AuthorMarco Alderighi,Claudio A. Piga
Date01 December 2014
Selection, Heterogeneity, and Entry in Professional
Markets
MARCO ALDERIGHI
Universit`
a della Valle d’Aosta
Aosta, Italy
and Universit`
a Bocconi, Milano, Italy
m.alderighi@univda.it
CLAUDIO A. PIGA
Keele University
Newcastle-under-Lyme, UK
and RCEA, Rimini, Italy
c.piga@keele.ac.uk
We analyze two different cases of entry regulation in professional markets: first, when licensing
is a requirement for becoming a professional (lawyers); second, when entry and price restrictions
are applied on a geographical basis (pharmacists). Both cases are investigated within a circular
model of localized competition and heterogeneous players. The analysis reveals that licensing
introduces a selection mechanism which is effective in preventing entry of inefficient players in
markets with large ex ante heterogeneity. Furthermore,because in the second case excessive entry
is reduced as the degree of heterogeneity increases, our analysis lends support to a policy that
simultaneously relaxes entry and price restrictions.
1. Introduction
The degree of efficiency in markets for such liberal professions as lawyers, notaries,
architects, engineers, and pharmacists has been the subject of extensive investigation
in Europe (European Commission, 2004).1The high level of regulation characterizing
the European market, in the form of either State regulation or self-regulation by profes-
sional bodies, has been deemed by some as unnecessary and harmful, while by others
as compelling and vital. For the latter, regulation is usually sustained by arguments
associated with the so called “public interest view” (i.e., regulation addresses market
failures due to asymmetric information, and/or externalities and/or public good pro-
vision). In contrast, those supporting the “private interest approach” claim that, due
to regulatory capture, many regulatory mechanisms may serve the private interests
of professional bodies’ members more than those of the general public (Stigler, 1971;
Posner, 1974; Peltzman, 1976; Becker, 1983; Philipsen, 2009). For instance, in the case of
Wewould like to thank the editor, the coeditor, and two anonymous referees of this journal for their valuable
suggestions and comments. Paul Dobson, Andr`
e de Palma, Francesco Passarelli, Joanna Poyago-Theotoky,
Jacques Thisse, Chris Wilson, and the participants of 2010 IIO Conference in Vancouver, of the 2010 EARIE
Conference in Instanbul, of the CCRP Workshop organizedby The City University, London, and all seminar
participants at CORE (Belgium) and York (UK) also kindly provideduseful feedback.
1. According to the EU Directive on Recognition of Professional Qualifications (2005/36/EC), liberal
professions are “those practised on the basis of relevant professional qualifications in a personal, responsible
and professionally independent capacity by those providing intellectualand conceptual services in the interest
of the client and the public.”
C2014 Wiley Periodicals, Inc.
Journal of Economics & Management Strategy, Volume23, Number 4, Winter 2014, 925–951
926 Journal of Economics & Management Strategy
entry restrictions, a requirement to have demonstrated basic competence is clearly jus-
tified where consumers are not well placed to assess the quality of service, as is usually
the case in markets for professional services. This has to be weighed against the risk
that necessary qualification thresholds may be set too high to constrain entry and thus
benefit incumbent producers, who largely control the professional bodies.
Based on the premise that in the real world some degree of firm heterogeneity
is the rule rather than the exception, in this study we deviate from the usual mar-
ket failure versus regulator capture arguments to provide a different and, in some
sense, complementary model for liberal professions, which allows an evaluation of
the welfare properties associated with (1) the entry requirement of licensing, (2) the
entry restrictions capping the maximum number of firms, and (3) fixed or minimum
prices.
Even within the European Union, professional regulation presents significant dif-
ferences among countries and professions, although there are also some important sim-
ilarities worldwide. As far as entry restrictions are concerned, for all professions a
university degree in the relevant field is required; for a subset of them (lawyers) the
exercise of the profession is conditional on the further acquisition of a licence which is
obtained by passing an examination and on spending a period of apprenticeship under
the supervision of a qualified professional (Kleiner, 2000). For other professions, e.g.,
pharmacists, no licensing is needed; in this case, however, rules on entry based on de-
mographic and geographic criteria often make it impossible to open a new outlet in
markets where such criteria are binding (Schaumans and Verboven, 2008).2
Wepropose a set-up that accommodates two main cases based on whether or not a
licence is required for the entry in the liberal profession. When licensing is not required,
entry is modeled as a two-stage game, where prospective entrants incur a set-up sunk
cost before starting production and the related competitive stage. To account for licens-
ing, we introduce a preliminary stage, where prospective professionals have to incur the
licensing sunk cost before deciding whether to start their activity or not. The opportu-
nity cost of the time spent to complete the apprenticeship period largely determines the
magnitude of the licensing cost. Thus, entry in professions where licensing is required
entails a three-stage process and two different sunk costs (i.e., the licensing cost as well
as the production set-up cost as in the no-licensing case).
Both types of entry games (i.e., with licensing and without) are analyzed in this
study by modeling the relevant market as a circular city model of localized competition
with heterogenous costs’ firms (Salop, 1979; Syverson, 2004; Vogel, 2008). To remain
in keeping with the terminology used in the existing literature, we will use the terms
“professional” and “firm” interchangeably.
The two games have different informational structures, which impact on the char-
acteristics of the ensuing equilibrium. In the two-stage game, before moving to the final
stage, players have no information about their own production costs, while in the li-
censing game, a professional learns her own cost after the licensing phase. Thus, this
second model entails a selection mechanism: only those professionals with sufficiently
low production costs will decide to enter the production stage by paying the second
set-up sunk cost.
2. Licensing and quantitative entry restrictions are not always mutually exclusive. For instance in Italy
they are both used to regulate entry into the notary profession,which is generally found to be highly regulated
across Europe (Philipsen, 2009).

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT