Securitization, Ratings, and Credit Supply

AuthorBRENDAN DALEY,VICTORIA VANASCO,BRETT GREEN
Published date01 April 2020
Date01 April 2020
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jofi.12866
THE JOURNAL OF FINANCE VOL. LXXV, NO. 2 APRIL 2020
Securitization, Ratings, and Credit Supply
BRENDAN DALEY, BRETT GREEN, and VICTORIA VANASCO
ABSTRACT
We develop a framework to explore the effect of credit ratings on loan origination.
We show that ratings endogenously shift the economy from a signaling equilibrium,
in which banks inefficiently retain loans to signal quality, toward an originate-to-
distribute equilibrium with zero retention and inefficiently low lending standards.
Ratings increase overall efficiency, provided that the reduction in costly retention
more than compensates for the origination of some negative net present value loans.
We study how banks’ ability to screen loans affects these predictions and use the
model to analyze commonly proposed policies such as mandatory “skin in the game.”
ASSET-BACKED SECURITIZATION IS AN IMPORTANT driver of credit supply (Lout-
skina and Strahan (2009), Shivdasani and Wang (2011)). In the United States,
since the mid-1990s, there has been substantial growth in the securitization
of many asset classes, including mortgages, student loans, commercial loans,
auto loans, and credit card debt. This practice has financed between 30% and
75% of loan amounts in these consumer lending markets (Gorton and Metrick
(2013)), significantly increasing households’ access to credit. The development
of markets for securitized products has been facilitated in part by credit rating
agencies (CRAs), which allow issuers access to a large pool of investors who
would otherwise have perceived these securities as opaque and complex (Coval,
Jurek, and Stafford (2009), Pagano and Volpin (2010)).
Brendan Daley is at Johns Hopkins University. Brett Green is at Washington University in
St. Louis. Victoria Vanasco is at Centre de Recerca en Economia Internacional (CREI), UPF, and
Barcelona GSE. Brett Green gratefully acknowledges support from the Fisher Center for Real
Estate and Urban Economics. The authors are grateful to Philip Bond, an anonymous associate
editor, and two anonymous referees for their valuable feedback and suggestions. We thank Bar-
ney Hartman-Glaser, Joel Shapiro, Anjan Thakor,Pablo Ruiz Verd ´
u, and Alessio Piccolo for their
thoughtful discussions. We are also grateful to seminar participants at Stanford GSB, CREI, Uni-
versitat Pompeu Fabra, CU Boulder, New York University,London School of Economics, Banco de
Portugal, University of North Carolina at Chapel Hill, Bendheim Center for Finance at Prince-
ton University, Washington University at St. Louis, McCombs School of Business at UT Austin,
Carlson School of Management at the University of Minnesota, Imperial College, London Business
School, ToulouseSchool of Economics, HEC Paris, and Wharton School of Business; and conference
participants at MADBAR, EIFE Junior Conference in Finance and the Economics of Credit Rat-
ings Conference at Carnegie Mellon, the Workshop on Corporate Debt Markets at Cass Business
School, NBER Corporate Finance Meeting, FIRS, Barcelona Summer Forum, and Oxford FIT for
helpful feedback and suggestions. We have read The Journal of Finance disclosure policy and have
no conflicts of interest to disclose.
DOI: 10.1111/jofi.12866
C2019 the American Finance Association
1037
1038 The Journal of Finance R
In the aftermath of the recent financial crisis, the practice of securitization
has been under intense scrutiny.The roles of originators in screening loans and
of rating agencies in evaluating securitized products have come into question.1
A variety of regulations have been proposed in an attempt to discipline loan
origination and protect investors. For example, the Dodd-Frank Act imposed a
mandatory “skin-in-the-game” rule on securitizers and established disclosure
requirements on both securitizers and rating agencies. Clearly, there are im-
portant interactions between the accuracy of information available to investors,
banks’ decisions with respect to which loans to originate, and the market for
securities backed by these loan pools. Yet, surprisingly, the academic literature
has little to say about these interactions.
In this paper, we propose a stylized model of origination and securitization
to analyze the role of both public and private information. We then explore
the implications for lending standards, credit supply, and welfare. Our main
finding is that the availability of public information, such as credit ratings,
improves the allocation of cash flow rights but reduces lending standards and
can lead to an oversupply of credit. Despite the potential for an oversupply
of credit, in most cases, total welfare increases with rating accuracy. We also
illustrate how the effectiveness of banks’ screening technology influences the
effect of ratings. With a better understanding of these forces, we investigate
the effects of common policy proposals, such as those described above from the
Dodd-Frank Act.
The model features a continuum of banks and a set of competitive and fully
rational investors. Each bank has access to a loan pool and uses a screening
technology to acquire private information about the quality of its loans.2Each
bank then decides whether to fund its pool—the origination stage. Following
origination, banks have an incentive to reallocate the cash flow rights from
their loan pool to investors (e.g., due to capital constraints) and do so by selling
securities backed by their loan pool in the secondary market—the securitiza-
tion stage. In this stage, the bank’s private information hinders the efficient
allocation of cash flow rights, which, in turn, distorts its incentives during the
origination stage.
The model admits two channels through which information can be conveyed
to investors to mitigate these distortions. First, because it is more costly for a
bank to retain bad loans than good ones, retention may serve to signal quality
to investors as in Leland and Pyle (1977). Banks’ ability to signal through
retention is consistent with evidence in Begley and Purnanandam (2017)
and Ivashina (2009), who study the markets for residential mortgage-backed
1See Dell’Ariccia, Igan, and Laeven (2012), Keys et al. (2010), Jaffee et al. (2009), Mian and Sufi
(2009), and Agarwal, Chang, and Yavas (2012) for how securitization negatively affects lending
standards, and Pagano and Volpin (2010) and Benmelech and Dlugosz (2010) for the role, and
failures, of CRAs in the securitization process.
2The assumption that banks acquire private information about borrowers at the loan screening
stage is consistent with findings in Mikkelson and Partch (1986), Lummer and McConnell (1989),
Slovin, Sushka, and Polonchek (1993), Degryse and Ongena (2005), Plantin (2009), Agarwal and
Hauswald (2010), and Botsch and Vanasco (2019).
Securitization, Ratings, and Credit Supply 1039
securities (RMBS) and syndicated loans, respectively.3Second, information
about the pool of loans underlying each security can be conveyed to investors
through a noisy public signal about the quality of the underlying collateral. We
refer to this signal as a rating, but it can be interpreted more broadly as any
form of public information. This rating is observed after the bank’s retention
decision but prior to the sale of the security. The primary question that we seek
to answer is how ratings affect lending standards and the supply of credit.
Toaddress this question, it is useful to describe the benchmark model without
ratings. Absent ratings or the release of other public information, the securiti-
zation stage is a standard signaling game where (least-cost) separation is the
unique stable outcome. Banks retain a positive fraction of the loan they issue
if they originated a good pool and sell 100% of their loan if they originated
a bad pool. By doing so, investors learn the quality of each loan sold on the
secondary market and prices fully reflect all available information. However,
because retention is costly,the bank does not realize the full social value of good
loans, which leads to inefficiently high lending standards and an undersupply
of credit.
When informative ratings are available, banks that originate good loan pools
no longer fully separate through retention. Instead, there is some degree of pool-
ing at a lower retention level.4Since retention is inefficient, ratings improve
allocative efficiency in the securitization stage.5But, because less is retained
and ratings are imperfect, their introduction actually reduces banks’ lending
standards and may induce an oversupply of credit. In essence, when ratings
are introduced, the equilibrium of the securitization stage endogenously shifts
from a signaling-through-retention equilibrium to an originate-to-distribute
(OTD) equilibrium, where banks forgo signaling and sell 100% of the loans
they originate.
There are two potential sources of inefficiency in our model. First, cash flow
retention may be inefficiently high due to asymmetric information at the se-
curitization stage, which induces banks to engage in costly signaling. Second,
lending standards may be inefficiently high or low since banks do not neces-
sarily internalize the social value of the loans they originate. More accurate
ratings reduce costly retention, but may also induce inefficiently low lending
standards. Therefore, ratings increase ex-ante efficiency,provided that the ben-
efits of reduced retention outweigh the costs of originating negative net present
value (NPV) loans. We show that these benefits necessarily outweigh the costs
when bank screening technology is sufficiently effective. Further, as ratings
3Adelino, Gerardi, and Hartman-Glaser (2019) find evidence of banks signaling their private
information about RMBS deals by delaying trade—a different form of cash flow retention that
could be studied within our context as well.
4A similar feature is present in Hartman-Glaser (2017), who shows that when sellers are able to
signal through both retention and reputation (as opposed to with a public signal), the equilibrium
is no longer separating.
5This result is consistent with empirical evidence that increased third-party certification, such
as ratings or number of analysts, increases a firm’s debt issuances and sometimes equity issuances
(Faulkender and Petersen (2005), Sufi (2007), Derrien and Kecsk´
es (2013)).

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT