Reverse Mortgage Loans: A Quantitative Analysis

AuthorMAKOTO NAKAJIMA,IRINA A. TELYUKOVA
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jofi.12489
Published date01 April 2017
Date01 April 2017
THE JOURNAL OF FINANCE VOL. LXXII, NO. 2 APRIL 2017
Reverse Mortgage Loans: A Quantitative Analysis
MAKOTO NAKAJIMA and IRINA A. TELYUKOVA
ABSTRACT
Reverse mortgage loans (RMLs) allow older homeowners to borrow against housing
wealth without moving. Despite rapid growth in this market, only 1.9% of eligible
homeowners had RMLs in 2013. In this paper, we analyze reverse mortgages in a
calibrated life-cycle model of retirement. The average welfare gain from RMLs is $252
per homeowner, and $1,770 per RML borrower. Bequest motives, uncertainty about
health and expenses, and loan costs account for low demand. According to the model,
the Great Recession’s impact differs across age, income, and wealth distributions,
with a threefold increase in RML demand for lowest income and oldest households.
REVERSE MORTGAGE LOANS (RMLs) allow older homeowners to borrow against
their housing wealth without moving out of the house, while insuring them
against significant drops in house prices. Despite potentially large benefits
to older individuals, many of whom want to stay in their house as long as
possible, frequent coverage in the media, and attempts by the Federal Housing
Administration, which administers RMLs, to modify the terms to increase their
appeal to borrowers, research on reverse mortgages is not extensive. This paper
helps fill some of this void.
In Nakajima and Telyukova (2013), we find that older homeowners become
borrowing-constrained as they age and these constraints force many retirees to
sell their homes when faced with large medical expenses. In this environment,
it seems that an equity borrowing product targeted toward older homeowners
may be able to relax that constraint, and hence potentially benefit many owners
later in life. Empirical studies suggest a similar possibility, though estimates
range widely. For example, while Merrill, Finkel, and Kutty (1994) suggest
that about 9% of homeowner households over age 69 could benefit from RMLs,
Rasmussen, Megbolugbe, and Morgan (1995) argue, using 1990 U.S. Census
Makoto Nakajima is with the Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia. Irina A. Telyukova is
with Intensity Corporation. We thank the Editor, Ken Singleton, and two anonymous referees
for constructive comments and valuable feedback. We also thank the participants of seminars
at Maastricht University, San Diego State University, University of Colorado Boulder, Federal
Reserve Bank of San Francisco, Stony Brook University,UC Irvine, UBC Sauder School, University
at Albany,UCSD, as well as the 2014 National Reverse Mortgage Association Meetings, 2013 FRB
St. Louis/University of Wisconsin HULM Conference, 2011 SAET Meetings in Faro, and 2011 SED
Meetings in Ghent, for their feedback. The views expressed here are those of the authors and do
not necessarily represent the views of the Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia or the Federal
Reserve System. We have read the Journal of Finance’s disclosure policy and have no conflicts of
interest to disclose. All errors are our own.
DOI: 10.1111/jofi.12489
911
912 The Journal of Finance R
data, that this number is nearly 80%.1Despite the apparent benefits, however,
just 1.9% of older homeowners held RMLs in 2013, down slightly from its all-
time high of 2.1% in 2011.
In this paper, we study determinants of demand for reverse mortgages, and
we consider its future post–Great Recession, in the face of complex trade-offs
that retirees face in deciding whether to borrow. Specifically, we address four
questions. First, we examine who benefits from reverse mortgages and by how
much, in welfare terms. Second, we investigate what prevents more retirees
from taking RMLs, given the current available RML contract. Here we focus
on retirees’ environment, such as the magnitude of risk that they face, and
preferences, such as their bequest motives. Third, we evaluate the impact of
the 2013 RML reform, and we study more generally whether and how the
existing reverse mortgage contract can be modified to make the RML more
attractive. Finally, we study how reverse mortgage demand may change as a
result of the Great Recession, which may have both a short-run and a long-run
impact on the financial security and incomes of future retirees.
To address these questions, we use a rich structural model of housing and
saving/borrowing decisions in retirement based on Nakajima and Telyukova
(2013). In the model, households are able to choose between homeownership
and renting, and homeowners can choose at any point to sell their house or
to borrow against their home equity. Retirees face uninsurable idiosyncratic
uncertainty in their life span, health, spouse’s mortality, medical expenses,
and house prices, and no aggregate uncertainty. Bad health states may force
older individuals into nursing homes, which we capture with an idiosyncratic
involuntary moving shock. The model is estimated to match life-cycle profiles
of net worth, housing and financial assets, homeownership rate, and home eq-
uity debt, which we construct from Health and Retirement Study (HRS) data,
controlling for time effects. Into this model, we introduce reverse mortgages,
study their use and value to different types of households, and conduct coun-
terfactual experiments to address the questions posed above. We find that the
model reproduces well key characteristics of the data, including many, though
not all, characteristics of the debt distribution, which are not targeted as part
of the estimation process.
The model predicts that the ex ante welfare benefit of reverse mortgages is
equivalent to providing a lump-sum transfer of $252 per retired homeowner
at age 65, which amounts to 0.84% of median annual after-tax income for this
group. The welfare gains are of course much larger for eventual borrowers,
amounting to $1,770 per borrower or 5.1% of median annual income. All home-
owners value, ex ante, the option of being able to tap their equity some time
during their retirement; however, ex post, only 0.89% of eligible retirees use
1Rasmussen, Megbolugbe, and Morgan (1995) assume that elderly households with home equity
exceeding $30,000 and without mortgage loans in 1990 benefit from having the option of obtaining
reverse mortgages. Merrill, Finkel, and Kutty (1994) assume that households with housing equity
between $100,000 and $200,000, income of less than $30,000 per year, a strong commitment to
stay in the current house (i.e., had not moved over the previous 10 years), and who own their house
free and clear benefit from reverse mortgages.
Reverse Mortgage Loans 913
RMLs in our model, which is close to the long-term data average of 0.84% be-
tween 1997 and 2013. Reverse mortgage demand is dampened by a combination
of substantial risks that households face late in life—such as health, medical
expense and long-term care risks, and house price uncertainty—as well as be-
quest motives, and significant costs of the contract. We find that the 2013 RML
reform is likely to further dampen demand going forward, stemming from its
tighter borrowing limit for most retirees, and in spite of lowered costs for some
borrowers.
More specifically, we find that retirees who use reverse mortgages tend to
have low income, low wealth, and poor health, and those who use them do
so primarily to support consumption expenditure in general, or in some cases
large medical expenses. While the aggregate take-up rate is less than 1%, it
is 2.2% for the lowest income quintile and 3.9% for low-income households
aged 90 and above. Bequest motives not only dampen RML demand, but also
change the way homeowners use RMLs; without a desire to bequeath, retirees
are over 17 times more likely to take RMLs, even without being pushed to do
so by a medical expense shock, and use them overwhelmingly for nonmedical
consumption. On the contract side, we find that eliminating up-front costs of the
loan more than triples demand for RMLs. In addition, reverse mortgages are
nonrecourse loans, which means that if the price of the collateral falls below
the loan value during the life of the RML, the lender cannot recover more
than the collateral value. Strikingly, we find that retirees do not value this
insurance component of RMLs due to low borrowed amounts and availability
of government-provided programs such as Medicaid. Thus, making the reverse
mortgage a recourse loan, which would remove substantial insurance premia
from the cost of the loan, would triple RML demand. In this sense, the oft-
heard claim that large contract costs suppress RML demand is supported by
our model. The FHA’s 2013 RML reform, in contrast, dampens demand in spite
of a lower up-front insurance cost for some retirees, because it also significantly
tightens the borrowing limit for most homeowners and raises insurance costs
for the most heavily indebted.
The Great Recession is likely to affect the RML market in different ways
in the short run and the long run. As a result of the recession, current re-
tirees have seen significant declines in housing and financial wealth. Thus,
in the short run, the aggregate RML take-up rate is likely to decline, from
0.89% to 0.71% in our model. However, the impact of the recession is heteroge-
neous across the income and wealth distributions: the most vulnerable retired
homeowners—those in the lowest income quintile in their 80s and 90s—may
have to rely increasingly on RMLs to finance their expenses. In this part of
the distribution, demand for RMLs may increase threefold. This raises impor-
tant policy trade-offs between the potentially increasing riskiness of the RML
portfolio held by the government and the need to provide access to one’s home
equity for those who most need it. In the long run, one impact of the Great
Recession will be lower incomes at retirement, stemming from protracted un-
deremployment spells earlier in the life-cycle. As a result of lower incomes,

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT