Resources and culture in organizations

Date01 October 2020
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jems.12388
Published date01 October 2020
AuthorMarcus Tomaino,Suraj Prasad
J Econ Manage Strat. 2020;29:854872.wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/jems854
|
© 2020 Wiley Periodicals LLC
Received: 23 August 2019
|
Revised: 8 June 2020
|
Accepted: 10 June 2020
DOI: 10.1111/jems.12388
ORIGINAL ARTICLE
Resources and culture in organizations
Suraj Prasad
1
|Marcus Tomaino
2
1
School of Economics, University of
Sydney, Sydney, New South Wales,
Australia
2
Department of Economics, University of
Pennsylvania, Philadelphia, Pennsylvania
Correspondence
Suraj Prasad, School of Economics,
University of Sydney, Sydney, NSW,
Australia.
Email: suraj.prasad@sydney.edu.au
Abstract
We look at how an organization's level of resources interacts with its culture
that is, its shared beliefs and preferences. We consider an organization where
workers exert effort to develop projects. These projects (a) have externalities
for other members, (b) compete for funds when resources are scarce, and (c)
can be implemented in various ways, which members have beliefs and pre-
ferences over. When resources are plenty, so that all feasible projects are
funded, workers' efforts are independent of each other and a coherent culture
is optimal. By contrast, when resources are scarce, competition across workers
with diverging beliefs or preferences (competing cultures) can be optimal.
1|INTRODUCTION
When thinking about motivation in organizations, economists tend to emphasize pay for performance, where a
worker's pay is tied to outcomes that benefit the organization. In practice, however, organizations rely on a richer set of
instruments to solve the motivation problem. One such instrument is the culture of the organizationthat is, the extent
to which beliefs and preferences are shared across members of the organization. The purpose of our paper is to provide
an economic way to think about some aspects of how culture motivates workers.
To see ways in which culture might serve as a motivational lever, consider the examples of the National Forest
Service (NFS) and the National Park Service (NPS)two U.S. government agencies with roughly similar functions, each
responsible for managing large tracts of land. In the NFS, new recruits who are selected carefully, undergo rigorous
training and are immediately indoctrinated in the ways of professional forest management. This ensures that their
performance is always in line with the overarching goal of the organization. In fact, as Herbert Kaufman notes in his
study of the NFS, foresters are if anything too zealous in their conformancetoward organizational policy (see
Kaufman, 1960, pp. 4, 5). We refer to such an organization, where members with shared beliefs and preferences work
toward the same outcome, as one with a coherent culture.
To compare, there is often conflict within the NPS over the proper way to manage these resources. Arguably, this is
driven by an inherent dualityin the selfstated purpose of the organization, which is to both conserve the scenery
and the natural and historic objectswhilst at the same time providing for the [public's] enjoymentof these natural
resources. With proponents on both sides of this argument within the organization, a question as simple as Should this
section of trees be cut back to enable easier access to camping grounds?can be hotly debated (Goodsell, 2011, pp. 111,
112.). Borrowing a phrase from James Q. Wilson in his book Bureaucracy (p. 92), we refer to this type of an organi-
zation, where members have diverging beliefs or preferences over outcomes, as one with competing cultures.
These views held by members of an organization matter in business settings too. At Facebook, for example,
disagreements over a plan to integrate services into a single privacyfocused platform led to the exit of two of its top
executives.
1
As one of the departing executives put it, we are turning a new page in our product direction. This will be
a big project and we will need leaders who are excited to see the new direction through.
At Microsoft, a focus on online (or cloud) computing led to disagreements within the organization over the role of
its traditional (and highly profitable) business for software for physical onsite servers (the Server and Tools Business).
2
To this end, Satya Nadella (the current CEO of Microsoft) was made the head of the Server and Tools Business (STB)
and was tasked with leading Microsoft's enterprise transformation into the cloud.To build shared contextfor this
cloudfirst strategy, Nadella set about assembling the right team,both from inside and outside the company (see
Iansiti & Serels, 2013, pp. 911; Nadella, Shaw, & Nichols, 2017; pp. 57, 58). He also made efforts to convince the whole
organization that the cloud was an integral part of STB's future.
We develop a framework to understand the implications that patterns of culture have for incentives in organiza-
tions. In particular, we examine how culture interacts with an organization's level of resources in the provision of
incentives.
In our model, a principal (the head of the organization) hires two agents (workers) to independently develop a
project each. Think of this as devising an initiativefor example, finding a way to improve trails in a national park, or
designing a new Facebook platform. Agents exert effort to ensure that their project is feasible. Infeasible projects are
discarded whereas feasible projects require funds for the developing agent to implement it. A funded project can be
implemented in one of many ways, which we model as points on a Hotelling line. In the national parks example, points
on the left of the line can be thought of as implementations that emphasize conservation whereas points on the right
emphasize recreation more. In the Facebook example, think of points on the left as applications that prioritize privacy
whereas points on the right are applications that do not.
There are three key elements in our model worth emphasizing. First, a project developed by one agent and
implemented in the organization has externalities for other members of the organization. These externalities take the
form of an expected benefit from the project, with the benefit being larger when the project is more aligned to the
member's preference. This leads to free riding in the organization and is the channel through which its members'
preferences and beliefs matter. Positive externalities arise naturally in missionoriented settings where workers care
about their organization's output. They also feature in business settings where a project developed by one member leads
to the overall success of the organization, which in turn benefits other members. This benefit could be because the
project complements existing products offered by other members, or it could be a reputational benefit from being part of
a successful organization.
Second, projects may have to compete with each other for funding. When resources are plenty, each feasible project
gets funded. With scarce resources, on the other hand, there is a cap on the number of feasible projects that can be
funded. In particular, when there are two feasible projects, one gets funded and the other does not. Although we
primarily think of resources in terms of funding, there are other interpretations that are consistent with our notion of
scarcitywhere there is a scarcity of slotsrelative to implementable projects in the organization. For example, an
organization may be constrained in taking multiple products to a market or different projects developed may be
incompatible with one another.
The third key element is the way we model culture. We assume that each member has an ideal point on the
Hotelling line which corresponds to an implementation that maximizes their expected benefit. The closer these ideal
points are in an organization, the more coherent its culture.
To begin with, we take the culture of an organization as exogenously given and see how it interacts with resources to
provide incentives. Later in our analysis, we endogenize this choice by allowing the head to select the ideal points of the
agents. There are two ways to interpret this choice. One is that agents are hired or selected to develop new projects
based on their observable beliefs and preferences. This interpretation applies more naturally to types of workers that
organizations have more information on, say those with more experience within or outside the organization, and those
in leadership positions who are scrutinized more carefully. The second interpretationwhich we do not model
explicitlyis that workers are socialized in the organization to shape their beliefs and preferences. This socialization
takes several forms: training, articulation of goals, and job rotation to broaden a worker's perspective. We discuss some
of these instruments to choose culture in more detail in our applications in Section 5.
When resources are plenty, so that all feasible projects can be funded, each agent is essentially a standalone unit
with dedicated resources for a feasible project. Efforts are thus independent across agents and do not depend on the
distribution of ideal points. As a result, the head prefers to hire agents who share his preferences over projects, so that a
coherent culture, if possible, is optimal. When resources are scarce, on the other hand, efforts are substitutes, a problem
exacerbated by externalities across projects which leads to free riding. Given that at most one feasible project can be
funded, and the benefit of implementation is nonrival, agents prefer to let each other bear the cost of effort of
development. Pushing agents' ideal points apart reduces the externality, rendering efforts less substitutable and thus
increasing the probability of successful project development. The cost of these competing cultures, however, is an
implementation which is less appealing to the head.
PRASAD AND TOMAINO
|
855

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT