Reaching for Yield in the Bond Market

Published date01 October 2015
Date01 October 2015
AuthorVICTORIA IVASHINA,BO BECKER
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jofi.12199
THE JOURNAL OF FINANCE VOL. LXX, NO. 5 OCTOBER 2015
Reaching for Yield in the Bond Market
BO BECKER and VICTORIA IVASHINA
ABSTRACT
This paper studies reaching for yield—investors’ propensity to buy riskier assets to
achieve higher yields—in the corporate bond market. We show that insurance com-
panies reach for yield in choosing their investments. Consistent with lower rated
bonds bearing higher capital requirements, insurance firms prefer to hold higher
rated bonds. However, conditional on credit ratings, insurance portfolios are system-
atically biased toward higher yield, higher CDS bonds. This behavior is related to the
business cycle being most pronounced during economic expansions. It is also charac-
teristic of firms with poor corporate governance and for which the regulatory capital
requirement is more binding.
AKEY PRINCIPLE OF FINANCE is that the evaluation of returns is only meaningful
on a risk-adjusted basis. However, risk is often hard to measure. This creates
an important limitation in the delegation of investment decisions. Financial in-
termediaries and investment managers that are evaluated based on imperfect
risk metrics face an incentive to buy assets that comply with a set benchmark
but are risky on other dimensions. In other words, imperfect benchmarks may
create incentives to “reach for yield” in the context of fixed income investing or
to reach for apparent “α” more generally. This could lead to excess risk-taking
in financial institutions, a persistent distortion in investment, and, potentially,
amplification of overall risk in the economy. Indeed, reaching for yield is be-
lieved to be one of the core factors contributing to the buildup of credit that
preceded the recent financial crisis (Rajan (2010) and Yellen1). Yet there is
Becker is with Stockholm School of Economics and Ivashina is with Harvard University and
NBER. We appreciate comments and suggestions from Jack Bao, Jeff Brown, Jess Cornaggia,
Hitesh Doshi, Ken Froot, Marcin Kacpercszyk (discussant), Peter Kondor,Chay Ornthanalai, Lasse
Pedersen, George Pennacchi, Andrei Shleifer, Jeremy Stein, Rene Stulz, Erik Stafford, Robert
Stambaugh, Marti Subrahmanyam, participants at the NBER Summer Institute, and seminar
participants at the Harvard Business School, Kansas City Federal Reserve, Michigan, Dartmouth,
Ohio State, New York, Bergen, Toronto, Stockholm, Miami, Tel Aviv Finance Conference, Oxford
(Sa¨
ıd), University of Pittsburgh, the SEC, Fordham, and the SFS Finance Cavalcade. We are
grateful for constructive feedback from Ken Singleton (Editor) and two anonymous referees. Matt
Kurzweil and Keith Osinski from TIAA-CREF and Matti Peltonen from the New York State De-
partment of Financial Services were very helpful in clarifying institutional details of the insurance
industry. We also thank Chris Allen, Lydia Petersen, Jennifer Rhee, and Baker Library Research
Services for assistance with data.
1Vice Chair of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System Janet L. Yellen,Remarks
at International Conference: Real and Financial Linkage and Monetary Policy, Bank of Japan,
June 1, 2011, http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/yellen20110601a.htm.
DOI: 10.1111/jofi.12199
1863
1864 The Journal of Finance R
a lack of clear empirical evidence on this phenomenon. This paper provides
an economically important example of reaching for yield and connects it to
investment decisions and incentives.
The incentive to search for apparent αis a broad phenomenon that is not
limited to any specific asset class, but it is likely be more pronounced for illiquid
and complex securities for which risk measurement is particularly problematic.
In this paper, we study reaching for yield in the context of corporate bonds. The
risk of corporate bonds and fixed income more generally is often assessed using
credit ratings. The advantage of credit ratings as a risk measure is that, due
to standardized and well-established scales, they are comprehensible and have
broad coverage for many fixed income securities. Ratings are also not affected
by liquidity or market conditions. Not surprisingly, ratings are commonly used
for contracting and regulation purposes. However, ratings tend to be updated
slowly (Cornaggia and Cornaggia (2013)), and depend on the accuracy of rating
methodology and the absence of agency conflicts (Becker and Milbourn (2011)).2
In addition, a bond’s credit rating primarily reflects the probability of default,
and losses given default, and does not capture the risk premium associated
with the default losses and other priced factors. More formally, for a bond i
YiRf EDefaultLossesi+RPi+αi
=PDi×LGDi+RPi+αi
=PDCR
i×LGDCR
i+[(PDi×LGDi
PDCR
i×LGDCR
i)+RPi]+αi,(1)
where YRf is the yield spread over the Treasury bond, PD is the market-
assessed probability of default, LGD is the market-assessed loss given default,
subscript CR indicates the parameter implied by credit ratings, RP is the risk
premium, and αis the abnormal return.3A proper performance benchmark
that would not give managers an incentive to take priced risk should include
true expected default losses and the risk premium. With such a benchmark,
the investment manager would have an incentive to find underpriced, positive
αbonds. But, if investment managers are evaluated and/or regulated based on
credit ratings, in which case the benchmark is PDCR ×LGDCR,they can beat
the benchmark by raising αor reaching for yield by taking on more priced risk
not captured in the benchmark (summarized by the term in brackets).
We focus on insurance companies, the largest institutional holder of corporate
and foreign bonds. According to the U.S. Flow of Funds Accounts, in 2010
insurance companies’ holdings represented $2.3 trillion, or more than bond
2In particular, several issues have been raised about the rating of structured products (e.g.,
Benmelech and Dlugosz (2009)).
3The risk premium could be further decomposed into the risk premium associated with default
losses and an illiquidity premium: YRf PD ×LGD +RP +LP +α.Theriskpremiummay
depend on how loss probabilities and magnitudes are associated with aggregate risk measures
(factors).
Reaching for Yield in the Bond Market 1865
holdings of mutual and pension funds taken together.4Regulation requires
insurance companies to maintain minimum levels of capital on a risk-adjusted
basis, often called “RBC” or risk-based capital. (On average, 91% of all securities
holdings by insurance companies are in fixed income (Nissim (2010)), making
the treatment of fixed income the core component of the RBC calculation.) To
determine the capital requirement for credit risk, corporate bonds are sorted
into six broad categories (National Association of Insurance Commissioners
(NAIC) risk categories 1 through 6) based on their credit ratings, with higher
categories subject to higher capital requirements.
To test for the reaching for yield phenomenon we need an unambiguous risk
benchmark. Due to the portfolio composition, the type of regulation, and the
presence of government guarantees, the insurance industry presents an impor-
tant and clear setting for studying this phenomenon. The central hypothesis
is that insurance companies may attempt to increase the yield in their bond
portfolio by taking on extra priced risk, while leaving capital requirements
unaffected. To test this prediction, we examine promised yield spreads and
spreads on credit default swaps (CDSs)5of insurance companies’ investments,
conditional on NAIC risk categories. Cox (1967) uses the term “reaching for
yield” to describe banks’ tendency to lend to high risk borrowers as a way to
increase the promised yield. Reaching for yield in the context of insurance firms
is similar because promised yields are used to determine earnings for insurance
firms. (We discuss this in more detail in Section I.B.)
Holdings data for the analysis come from Lipper eMAXX and cover the
2004:Q1 to 2010:Q3 period, which we divide into before and after the finan-
cial crisis. The data have comprehensive coverage of quarterly fixed income
holdings by individual insurance companies, mutual funds, and pension funds.
Our basic finding for the precrisis period is illustrated in Figure 1.Inthis
figure, insurance firms’ investment behavior is benchmarked against other in-
vestors in our sample. Whereas insurance companies face capital requirements
imposed by regulators based on credit ratings, this is not the case for mutual
and pension funds. In terms of equation (1), the benchmark for insurance firms
is PDNAIC ×LGDNAIC while that for mutual and pension funds is closer to
(PD ×LGD +RP). Because of this difference in risk assessment for insurance
firms, if insurers reach for yield we should find higher relative propensity to buy
high-yielding assets. (This is not to say that mutual and pension funds do not
reach for yield, but reaching behavior for these institutions would be driven by
factors other than credit ratings and manifest itself differently.)Figure 1, Panel
A shows that, consistent with risk-weighted capital requirements, insurance
companies exhibit a strong preference for safer bonds. However, the opposite
is true within regulatory risk categories (Figure 1, Panel B). For securities
4Investment decisions of insurance companies are also important because, like banks, insurance
companies have liabilities to a broad population base.
5An advantage of using CDS spreads in addition to yields is that they may be affected by
illiquidity in a different way from positive net supply assets like bonds (Bongaerts, De Jong, and
Driessen (2011)).

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT