Rater Bias and Incentive Provision

Published date01 October 2015
AuthorPhilipp Weinschenk,Daniel Müller
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jems.12118
Date01 October 2015
Rater Bias and Incentive Provision
DANIEL M¨
ULLER
University of Bonn
Adenauerallee 24 D-53113 Bonn, Germany
daniel.mueller@uni-bonn.de
PHILIPP WEINSCHENK
Technical Universityof Kaiserslautern
Gottlieb-Daimler-Straße D-67663
Kaiserslautern Germany; and
Max Planck Institute for Research on Collective Goods
Kurt-Schumacher-Str. 10 D-53113 Bonn, Germany
weinschenk@coll.mpg.de
The tendency of supervisors to judge an employee as either good or bad and then to seek out
evidence supporting that earlier established opinion is regarded as one of the major problems
of performance appraisal. We investigate the implications of this rater bias in a dynamic moral
hazard model with a wealth-constrained agent. Although rater bias weakens the agent’sincentives
to exert effort in late periods, at the same time it strengthens implicit incentives in early periods.
Under the optimal contract, as long as rater bias is not overly strong, its adverse effect on late-
period incentives is fully offset by exploitation of stronger early-period incentives and thereby
leaves the principal’s profits unchanged.
1. Introduction
A widespread instrument for incentive provision within firms and organizations is the
implementation of a merit pay plan in combination with some kind of performance ap-
praisal process. Contingent pay is seen as a fair and equitable way to reward employees
differentially for their different contributions and—by linking pay to performance—to
motivate employees to perform better.1Many firms, however, rely (at least to some ex-
tent) on performance measures which are subjective rather than objective in nature, that
is, where an employee’s pay is at the discretion of the impressions of a supervisor.2This
makes performance appraisal a process by which humans judge other humans, thereby
opening the door for behavioral biases and inferential errors to enter and to distort
this process. Rater bias in general is considered a severe problem because “[b]iased and
In preparing this paper, we have benefited from comments made by Oliver Hart, Fabian Herweg, Matthias
Kr¨
akel, Patrick Schmitz, and Fritz Strack. We also thank the conference audiences at the Nordic Conference
on Behavioral and Experimental Economics (Helsinki, 2010) and at the IMEBE (Barcelona, 2011) as well as the
seminar participants at the University of Marburg and the University of W¨
urzburg for helpful comments.
1. For textbook expositions on the basic functions of and problems with performance appraisal, see, for
example, Porter et al. (2008) or Dessler (2008).
2. For example, Murphy and Oyer (2003) find that 67% of 280 U.S. firms display discretion in the allocation
of a bonus pool across participants. Likewise, as reported in Baker et al. (1994), half a worker’s pay at Lincoln
Electric comes froma bonus based on subjective aspects of performance, for example, the worker’s cooperation,
innovation, or dependability. For a comprehensive review of the theoretical and empirical literature on the
rationales for and the problems associated with the use of subjective performance measures, see Prendergast
(1999).
C2015 Wiley Periodicals, Inc.
Journal of Economics & Management Strategy, Volume24, Number 4, Winter 2015, 833–862
834 Journal of Economics & Management Strategy
inaccurate performance evaluation reduces productivity by reducing the effectiveness
of incentives in the organization” (Baker et al., 1988, p. 608). 3
In this paper, we formally inquire into the implications for incentive provision
and optimal contract design when the evaluation of an employee’s performance is di-
rectionally influenced by that employee’s past appraisal records.4More specifically, we
model the tendency of supervisors to judge an employee’s performance as either good
or bad and then to reaffirm that previously established opinion in subsequent ratings of
later performance. The cognitive processes that have been hypothesized to drive such
spillover or assimilation effects in appraisal patterns are manifold. For example, accord-
ing to the priming hypothesis, the use of cognitive categories that reflect the quality of
work behavior in organizing one’s perception of previous performance increases the
probability of using the same categories again when evaluating present performance.
Likewise, though operating at a different level of information processing, hypothesis
confirmation bias is conjectured to lead individuals to seek out information that con-
firms their early impressions, and to discount disconfirmatory information.5
These spillover effects—by whatever cognitive process they are brought about—
are commonly acknowledged to lead to a distortion of the appraisal process which
constitutes a source of employee frustration, in particular for those employees who
are discriminated against, and in turn deteriorates incentive provision and firm perfor-
mance.
Toallow for past performance records to prejudice current performance evaluation,
we set up a moral hazard framework in which a risk-neutral agent, who has no resources
of his own, decides in two consecutive periods how much effort to exert. 6In each period,
the agent’s unobservable effort decision influences the realization of a performance
measure. Although the performance measure itself is (at least partially) subjective and
therefore cannot be contracted upon, the supervisor’s reports are verifiable and can be
used for contracting purposes. The supervisor’s perception of the performance measure,
however, does not necessarily coincide with its actual realization: whenever the agent’s
second-period performance does not match his first-period performance record, the
supervisor tends to misperceive the agent’s performance in the second period as identical
to his first-period performance. In what follows, we refer to this stylized notion of current
appraisal being prejudiced by past performance records plainly as rater bias.
In contrast to the prevalent opinion in human resource management, we find that
the implications of rater bias for incentive provision and overall performance are by
far not as dire as common wisdom suggests. Admittedly, rater bias makes provision of
second-period incentives more difficult: the value of high effort for an employee who
has received an unfavorable first evaluation is diminished by rater bias because a second
poor evaluation becomes more likely even when he puts much devotion into his task;
likewise, an employee who was rated favorably during the first period does not consider
exertion of high effort to be very necessary,because due to rater bias a second favorable
3. Likewise, according to Murphy (1992), “[t]he success of companywide incentive compensation pro-
grams therefore depends on managers’ effectiveness in monitoring and appraising performance.” (p. 37)
4. Our paper is thus closely related to the literature on biased ratings and incentive provision. See, for
example, Prendergast and Topel(1996), Prendergast (2002), and Giebe and G ¨
urtler (2012) on the implications
of favoritism and the leniency bias for incentive design.
5. See, for example, Murphy et al. (1985) for an overview of these and alternative cognitive processes
resulting in assimilation effects in performance evaluation.
6. For other papers considering limited liability of a risk-neutral agent in a repeated moral hazard frame-
work, see, for example, Cr´
emer (1995), Che and Yoo (2001), Schmitz (2005a, 2005b, 2013), Ohlendorf and
Schmitz (2012), and Kr¨
akel and Sch¨
ottner (2010).

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT