Quotas, Productivity, and Prices: The Case of Anchovy Fishing

Date01 March 2016
AuthorGabriel Natividad
Published date01 March 2016
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jems.12148
Quotas, Productivity, and Prices:
The Case of Anchovy Fishing
GABRIEL NATIVIDAD
Department of Economics
Universidad de Piura
162 Martir Olaya St. Lima 18 Peru
gabriel.natividad@udep.pe
I exploit a 2009 reform that introduced individual fishing quotas (catch shares) for Peruvian
anchovy—the largest fishery in the world—to assess the causal impact of production quotas on
within-firm productivity and market prices. Unique features of the data allow me to create two
alternative counterfactuals: (i) anchovy fishing operations in a region of the country that was
mandated to implement quotas with a delay, and (ii) variation in quota allocations across ships.
I find that quotas do not increase within-asset or within-firm productivity in quantities. Instead,
a 200% increase in anchovy prices benefits extraction firms through higher revenues, consistent
with two mechanisms enacted by individual fishing quotas: more orderly industry operations
reducing excess supply and an increase in bargaining power of extraction firms with respect
to fish-processing. Several market characteristics across geographies differentially affect market
prices after the quota regime. Supplementary evidence on fewer operational infractions, higher
product quality, and a lower banking delinquency observed during the quota regime suggests the
existence of efficiency gains rather than purely rent transfers.
A rising literature in industrial organization has brought into relief the broad market
impact of environmental regulation (Greenstone, 2002; Keller and Levinson, 2002; Davis,
2008; Greenstone et al., 2012; Ryan, 2012). From an economic standpoint, one of the chief
difficulties of regulating the environment consists in addressing the tragedy of the com-
mons in natural resource contexts (Stavins, 2011), a problem often requiring the granting
of property rights to private firms (Vander Ploeg, 2011). This paper presents new causal
evidence about the impact of individual fishing quotas on within-firm productivity and
market prices by exploiting a 2009 reform that radically changed access to Peruvian
anchovy, the largest fishery in the world.
It has been argued that individual fishing quotas—an instrument that restricts free
access to the common fishery (Gordon, 1954), assigning to each ship a pre-established
catch share—can prevent the collapse of global fisheries (Costello et al., 2008; Heal and
Schlenker, 2008). Accordingly, over the last two decades, there has been much interest
in analyzing marine resource property rights in the form of individual fishing quotas
I am grateful to the Ministry of Production of Peru, to IMARPE, and to three fishing firms whose names are
suppressed here for confidentiality for access to data. No confidential information is disclosed in this paper.
Many thanks to John Asker and Natarajan Balasubramanian for valuable insights at different stages of this
project, and to an anonymous co-editor,two referees, Hunt Allcott, Alessandro Gavazza, AviGoldfarb, Deepak
Hegde, Boyan Jovanovic, Virgiliu Midrigan, Joseph Ostroy, Michael Powell, Rob Seamans, Giorgio Zanarone,
Peter Zeitz and audiences at City University of New York, Colegio Universitario de Estudios Financieros,
National University of Singapore, New YorkUniversity, Seoul National University,Universidad de Piura and
the ISNIE annual conference for useful comments. Guillermo Ramirez and Javier Romero Haaker provided
excellent research assistance. All errors are mine.
C2015 Wiley Periodicals, Inc.
Journal of Economics & Management Strategy, Volume25, Number 1, Spring 2016, 220–257
Anchovy Fishing 221
(see Scott (1993, 2000, 2008), Libecap (2009), and Branch (2009) for broad discussions
and reviews). This large body of work has often focused on specific studies of fisheries
adopting a quota system1or cross-fishery comparisons of quota systems.2However,this
literature has given relatively little attention to the causal impact of fishing quota regimes
on within-firm productivity and market prices, thus remaining somewhat disconnected
from ongoing research in industrial organization.
As more direct background to my study, a small number of papers have employed
natural experiments to investigate the influence of individual fishing quotas on produc-
tivity and prices. Grafton et al. (2000) and Fox et al. (2003) analyze productivity and
prices around the introduction of individual harvesting rights in the British Columbia
halibut fishery in 1991, utilizing different cross-sectional samples of firms from 1988,
1991, and 1994, and finding changes in outcomes during the quota regime. Brandt (2007)
and Walden et al. (2012) employ the introductionof quotas in the Mid-Atlantic surfclam
and ocean quahog fisheries to study vessel productivity and participation incentives
before and after the reform. Importantly, all this prior work has lacked the econometric
advantage of having a control group to isolate the causal impact of the quota system
treatment. Moreover, some of these studies have lacked disaggregated information on
local market prices and weekly dynamics that would speak to current research on eco-
nomics mechanisms in vertical markets (e.g., Syverson, 2007; Hortac¸ su and Syverson,
2007).
My analysis of the industrial organization of fishing quotas fills an important gap in
the literature because key market outcomes should not be expected to remain unchanged
after quotas are enacted. Specifically,individual fishing quotas can be broadly construed
as a government-mandated reduction of competition in a given market, which may
carry implications for firm productivity and market prices (see Holmes and Schmitz
(2010) for the more frequently studied cases of increases in competition). Moreover,
the market structure analysis of fishery reforms is particularly important given their
potential redistributive effects (Karpoff, 1987). In this paper, I exploit a comprehensive
data set to assess the causal impact of individual fishing quotas, with emphasis on the
joint analysis of productivity and prices in the context of competitive markets.
In essence, I seek to answer two basic questions: How and why do individual
fishing quotas matter for asset-level productivity? And how and why do these quotas
matter for market prices? From a conceptual standpoint, answers to the first question can
1. For example, Geen and Nayar (1988) employ a simulation framework to compare a quota system with
other regulatory systems in the Southern bluefin tuna fishery in Australia and Japan; Casey et al. (1995)
collect descriptive statistics of the impact of a halibut individual fishing quota by conducting a round of 14
interviews with halibut processors in 1993 and by conducting one mail survey of all halibut fishermen in
1994; Herrmann (1996) studies the yearly aggregate time series of halibut prices in Canada before and after
the adoption of a quota system; Campbell et al. (2000) describe broad economic patterns emerging after the
enactment of individual transferrable quotas in Australia’s southern bluefin tuna fishery; Dupont and Grafton
(2000) analyze multi-species individual transferable quotas; Dupont et al. (2005) also analyze multi-species
individual transferable quotas, and although their focus is on productivity and prices, they analyze data in a
more aggregate(industry-species level) fashion; Fox et al. (2006) study the posterior introduction in Australia’s
Southeast trawl fishery of both a brokerage system enhancing the transferability of individual quotas and a
government-sponsored buy-back program for fishing licenses; Sharp and Batstone (2008) discuss the simul-
taneous introduction of total allowable catch (TAC) and individual transferrable quotas in New Zealand’s
fisheries management environment; Sylvia et al. (2008) describe the introduction of a self-government body,
the Pacific Whiting Conservation Cooperative, acknowledged to be quite different from an individual quota
system; Lee and Thunberg (2013) analyze a catch share system creating a simulated counterfactual based on
pre-regime operations
2. For instance, Chu (2009) and Essington (2010) conduct cross-fishery comparisons of ITQ adoption and
subsequent ecological outputs, with a clear biological emphasis rather than a focus on economic outcomes.
222 Journal of Economics & Management Strategy
vary widely. By reducing competition (racing behavior) through guaranteeing a catch
share to all market participants, a quota system may have a positive impact on within-
ship productivity through a smoother, better planned exploitation of the resource. But
when such guarantee helps industry participants reduce a significant portion of their
assets (ships), the remaining assets would need to be operated more intensively than
before, while lacking some of the prior information and incentive mechanisms due to the
presence of excess ships, thus becoming less productive with quotas. The question about
market prices appears to be more intuitively answered: by granting property rights to
fish extraction companies, the price of fish sold downstream should increase. Yet the
mechanism for price increases may vary, perhaps enacting a shift in bargaining power
over the vertical chain or instead more orderly supply operations due to the benefits of
fishing without racing. Generally, there has been much theoretical interest in modeling
fishermen’s racing behavior and the individual quota instrument (e.g., Gordon, 1954;
Arnason, 1990; Boyce, 1992). The causal impact of quotas on productivity and prices is
the open empirical question that I address.
The enactment of individual fishing quotas in the Peruvian anchovy fishery implied
a significant regulatory shift affecting all firms in the industry. Historically, until 2008,
extraction firms operated under a regulatory framework that allowed all ships with
a license to fish anchovy for fishmeal—an intermediate good produced by plants on
land—until a “total allowable catch” was reached. No individual caps on ship output
existed. In this early regime, the primary concern of firms was to find anchovy,extract as
much of it as possible, and deliver it quickly to plants to restart this cycle, aware that fish
not caught by one firm would be caught by another. In 2008, the government suddenly
introduced a new regulatory framework, with the stated goals of reducing overcapacity
and discouraging racing behavior that exerted pressure on the natural environment. In
the new fishing regime, a total allowable catch was still in place, but each ship received
an individual fishing quota, defined as a percentage share of the total allowable catch.
Individual fishing quotas were allocated using a formula based on ship characteristics
and ship output from 2004 to 2007 (i.e., a period ending before the announcement of
the reform). Moreover,the new regulation allowed firms to transfer quotas across ships,
thus fostering the closure of less productive ships once their quotas were transferred
away to others.
Key features of this regulatory reformallow me to study the causal impact of quotas
in a reduced-form fashion.3To be sure, a quota reform is an event among others poten-
tially affecting industry structure, so it is typically difficult to isolate the causal effect of
quotas without a clear counterfactual. By contrast, the reform studied here allows me to
exploit two counterfactuals for the question of interest: (i) anchovy fishing operations in
a region of the country that was ruled to implement quotas with a delay with respect to
the region of interest, and (ii) variation in quota allocations across ships. In a first set of
tests, I exploit data on anchovy fishing in the South region of the Peruvian sea, which
was scheduled to begin its own quota regime a few months later than the North-Center
region (i.e., the region of interest for my study, totaling over 87% of historical anchovy
catches.) The results of within-ship and within-firm panel difference-in-differences re-
gressions with respect to the South region counterfactual show no positive influence
of the advent of the quota regime on productivity measured in quantities. In a sec-
ond set of tests, I exploit ship-specific quota allocations to study the within-ship and
3. See Huang and Smith (2014) for a structural estimation of common pool extraction efficiency in the U.S.
shrimp industry in which policy experiments different from individual fishing quotas are discussed.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT