Public Report, Price, and Quality

Date01 June 2014
Published date01 June 2014
AuthorChing‐to Albert Ma,Henry Y. Mak
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jems.12050
Public Report, Price, and Quality
CHING-TO ALBERT MA
Department of Economics
Boston University
270 Bay State Road, Boston, MA 02215
ma@bu.edu
HENRY Y. MAK
Department of Economics
Indiana University-Purdue University Indianapolis
425 University Boulevard, Indianapolis, IN 46202
makh@iupui.edu
A monopolist produces a good with two qualities. All consumers have the same valuation of the
first quality, but their valuations of the second vary, and are their private information. A public
agency can verify qualities, and make credible reports to consumers. In Full Quality Report, the
public agency reports both qualities. In Average Quality Report, it reports a weighted average
of qualities. The equilibrium prices and qualities in Full Quality Report can be implemented
by Average Quality Report. Equilibrium prices and qualities in Average Quality Report give
higher consumer surplus than Full Quality Report. Bertrand competition under Average Quality
Report yields first-best prices and qualities.
1. Introduction
Empowering consumers with product information is often regardedas a plausible way to
solve the problems of experience goods, whose qualities are unknown before purchase.
This information often comes in the form of ratings and rankings. For example, US
News and World Report (USNWR ) ranks colleges and graduate schools. The National
Commission on Quality Assurance (NCQA), which works with the Centers for Medicare
& Medicaid Services, compares health care providers, insurance plans, and nursing
homes across the United States. Consumer Reports rates consumer products and services
by indexes. Such information generally can be regarded as a form of quality index.
What is the impact of quality index on market outcomes? It is clear that firms react
to quality indexes. For example, when the British hospital rating system assigned zero
weight to women and children services, clinicians reported that hospitals reduced those
qualities (Mannion et al., 2005). Stake (2006) discusses how the USNWR Law School
Ranking has affected resource allocation in law schools. Obviously, consumers should
be mindful about firms’ reactions. Regulatory agencies and watchdog organizations
We thank Sambuddha Ghosh, Jacob Glazer, Steve Matthews, and seminar participants at Boston University,
Carlos III Universidad de Madrid, City University of Hong Kong, Duke University, INSEE, University of
Munich, University of Naples Fedrico II, the US Department of Justice, the Ninth Annual International
Industrial Organization Conference in Boston, and the 10th Annual Columbia-Duke-Northwestern IO Theory
Conference for their comments. Wealso thank a Coeditor and two referees for their advice. Part of this research
was done while the first author was visiting Carlos III Universidad de Madrid, and TuftsUniversity and while
the second author was with the Max Weber Programme at the European University Institute; their financial
support and hospitality are acknowledged.
C2014 Wiley Periodicals, Inc.
Journal of Economics & Management Strategy, Volume23, Number 2, Summer 2014, 443–464
444 Journal of Economics & Management Strategy
should educate consumers on how quality indexes are to be used. A deeper question,
however, is how quality indexes should be constructed. In this paper, we study optimal
quality indexes.
We study quality index as a mechanism design problem. In our model, a public
agency announces how quality indexes are to be constructed. A monopolist produces
goods with multiple quality attributes, then chooses prices to offer them to consumers.
The qualities of each offered good are observed by the public agency, and the indexes
will be constructed according to the decided rules. The quality indexes are then disclosed
to consumers. Finally,consumers decide whether to purchase at the set prices. We derive
the optimal quality indexes for the maximization of consumer welfare.
Our main result is that the optimal quality indexes generate more consumer and
social surpluses than when all quality information is disclosed to consumers. If the public
agency releases all quality information, the firm freely chooses its second-degree price-
quality discrimination strategies. If the public agency discloses only quality indexes, but
not all information, the firm must choose its qualities optimally to achieve any index.
Consumers therefore infer that only such qualities are equilibrium choices. This actually
restrains the firm’s price-quality discrimination strategies. Therefore, carefully chosen
indexes can benefit consumers.
We call the above the Average Quality Report regime, where indexes are weighted
averages of a firm’s product qualities. When the public agency discloses all quality
information, we call that the Full Quality Report regime. Qualities and prices under
Average Quality Report generate higher consumer welfare than Full Quality Report.
The result remains true if the public agency aims to maximize a weighted sum of
consumer surplus and profits (with a lower weight on profits), or if the public agency
bans second-degree price-quality discrimination.
The two regimes generate the same consumer surplus when the market is compet-
itive. In this case, the public agency releasing all information will implement the first
best, so Full Quality Report is optimal. The interesting observation is that the public
agency can implement the first best by Average Quality Report. The public agency can
construct the indexes to implement first-best quality strategic responses.
A provocative policy implication of our model is the regulation of quality certifi-
cation. Average Quality Report imposes a constraint on the monopolist. Therefore, the
monopolist would like to hire a third party to verify its product qualities to remove the
constraint. Consumers are better off if the government disallows the monopolist to hire
its own certification agent. The government then intervenes by observing the qualities
and reporting optimal quality indexes. Our model provides a justification for why many
reports are indexes and compiled by nonprofit and public organizations.
Many papers study how quality information influences the interaction between
firms and consumers. In Matthews and Postlewaite (1985) and Schlee (1996), quality is
one dimensional, exogenously given, but may be unknown to either the firm, consumers,
or both. These papers compare full quality disclosure and nondisclosure. They show
that quality information may harm consumers due to the seller responding with higher
prices. By contrast, in this paper, the firm chooses both prices and multiple qualities.
Here, nondisclosure will lead to the collapse of the market. Full disclosure allows the
firm to perform second-degree price-quality discrimination. Partial disclosure in our
model benefits consumers by restraining the firm’s price and quality strategies.
Several recent papers analyze disclosure of multiple quality attributes. In Sun
(2011) and Hotz and Xiao (2013), firms produce a good with both horizontal and vertical
attributes. These papers show that neither a monopolist nor duopolists may disclose an

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT