Public and Nonprofit Higher Education as the Optimal Second‐Best

AuthorRobert Shireman
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/puar.12577
Published date01 September 2016
Date01 September 2016
758 Public Administration Review September | October 2016
Public Administration Review,
Vol. 76, Iss. 5, pp. 758–759. © 2016 by
The American Society for Public Administration.
DOI: 10.1111/puar.12577.
Robert Shireman is a senior fellow at
The Century Foundation, working on issues
related to education policy. He served in
the Clinton White House as senior policy
adviser to the National Economic Council
and later for the Obama Administration as
deputy undersecretary in the Department of
Education. He holds a bachelor s degree in
economics from the University of California
at Berkeley, a master’s degree in education
from Harvard, and a master’s degree in
public administration from the University of
San Francisco.
E-mail: shireman@tcf.org
Perspective
A
reporter who covers Wall Street recently asked
me whether the for-profit college industry
has hit bottom yet. She meant the stock price,
but my mind went immediately to the predatory
behavior—aggressive and misleading marketing and
low-quality programs leading hundreds of thousands
of students into crippling debt—that has plagued the
industry. Those egregious practices were at their worst
precisely when the stock prices of for-profit colleges
were at their highest. And therein lies the market
failure that burdens for-profit higher education: While
in other industries consumer value and shareholder
value can move in tandem, with products and services
like education, the guiding light of the enterprise—
the stock price—can lead to the worst outcomes for
students.
Education exhibits a problem known as contract
failure, in which the buyer cannot reliably evaluate
the quality of the promised or provided product or
service. As a consequence, profit maximization fails to
produce optimal outcomes because the profit-seekers’
drive to overpromise and underdeliver is rewarded
rather than punished by the market, causing other
firms to emulate the bad behavior. The problem
becomes particularly severe if the firms target the least
sophisticated or most desperate customers, those who
are least able to evaluate the quality of the service
provided. Contract failure is common in enterprises
with ambiguous goals like building character,
developing critical thinking skills, or spiritual
fulfillment, or in industries involving vulnerable
populations like children (schools) and the elderly
(nursing homes).
Note that the school owners’ problematic behavior
is not necessarily illegal, such as outright deception.
More commonly, the strategies involve legal but sleazy
strategies that shortchange consumers in ways that
are difficult to detect or interpret (such as employing
a less-qualified instructor), or can be blamed on the
customers themselves (they didn t come to class).
Sleaziness is a judgment call, not an easily enforceable
boundary like a speed limit. Law enforcement and
monitoring strategies, therefore, are inadequate for
steering the market toward optimal outcomes for
consumers. Rather than rewarding the best providers,
law enforcement alone rewards the firms that hew
closest to the illegal line, which means consumers and
taxpayers are not getting the value they deserve for the
money. Having colleges that are not outright corrupt is
a step in the right direction, but it is far from optimal.
There is one restriction, however, that actually does
a demonstrably effective job of preventing both
the illegal and sleazy behavior in contract-failure
situations. That restriction is what economists call
a nondistribution constraint . The nondistribution
constraint is a requirement that the revenue of a firm
always be used for the enterprise itself, rather than
being distributed to any owners or shareholders. Most
people do not recognize the nondistribution constraint
as a “regulation” because it is hidden as part of the core
definition of public and other nonprofit enterprises.
Predatory behavior is more common and more severe
at for-profit colleges than at nonprofits for one simple
reason: the lack of the nondistribution constraint.
We can think of education as exhibiting what the
economists Richard Lipsey and Kelvin Lancaster in
1956 described as the theory of second best: When
one condition of the optimal economic model cannot
be satisfied, adding a second distortion—in this case
the nondistribution constraint—can lead to the more
efficient outcome, even though it is the second-best
approach. The “best”—the market in which the profit
motive and consumers’ perfect knowledge leads to the
best value for the price—is not achievable. But the
“second-best,” the optimal condition, is one that can
exhibit many characteristics that appear (but may or
may not be) inefficient from an optimality standpoint.
In higher education the arguably inefficient choices
include esoteric courses, sprawling campuses, small
classes, limited and selective enrollments, constrained
schedules, professors who spend time on research
Robert Shireman
The Century Foundation
Public and Nonprofit Higher Education
as the Optimal Second-Best

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT