Product Unbundling in the Travel Industry: The Economics of Airline Bag Fees

Date01 September 2015
Published date01 September 2015
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jems.12106
Product Unbundling in the Travel Industry: The
Economics of Airline Bag Fees
JAN K. BRUECKNER
Department of Economics
University of California
Irvine, CA 92697 USA
jkbrueck@uci.edu
DARIN N. LEE
Compass Lexecon
200 State Street, 9th Floor Boston, MA 02109
darin.lee@compasslexecon.com
PIERRE M. PICARD
Department of Economics
University of Luxembourg
Campus Limpertsberg 162 A, avenue de la Fa¨
ıencerie L-1511 Luxembourg
pierre.picard@uni.lu
ETHAN SINGER
Department of Economics
University of Minnesota
1925 4th St S, Room 4-101 Minneapolis, MN 55455
singe119@umn.edu
This paper provides theory and evidence on airline bag fees, offering insights into a real-world case
of product unbundling. The theory predicts that an airline’s fares should fall when it introduces
a bag fee, but that the full-trip price (the bag fee plus the new fare) could either rise or fall. The
empirical evidence presented in the paper provides strong confirmation of the first prediction. The
data also suggest that the average fare falls by less than the bag fee itself so that the full price of a
trip rises for passengers who choose to check bags.
1. Introduction
Product bundling and unbundling by firms has been a focus of researchers in industrial
organization ever since the seminal contributions of Stigler (1963) and Adams and Yellen
(1976).1Although consumers may have only been vaguely aware of the impact of firm
A portion of the empirical work in this paper is based on analysis contained in an expert report by Darin Lee,
who was retained by Delta Air Lines in connection with a class action litigation filed in U.S. Federal Court.
However, the opinions expressed areentirely ours. We thank an associate editor and a number of referees for
helpful comments.
1. In addition to Adams and Yellen (1976) and Stigler (1963), see Schmalensee (1982) and Lewbel (1985)
for other early papers on bundling. The literature presents models where consumers demand either zero
or one unit of different products. Firms can offer no bundles, pure bundles or mixed bundles according to
whether they offer their products separately,jointly, or in both fashions. The literature emphasizes the result
that monopolies have incentives to bundle products to discriminate among consumers. Evans and Salinger
(2005, 2008) emphasize cost-savings from bundling as another force behind the practice. The related tie-in
C2015 Wiley Periodicals, Inc.
Journal of Economics & Management Strategy, Volume24, Number 3, Fall 2015, 457–484
458 Journal of Economics & Management Strategy
bundling decisions on the product choices available to them, recent developments in the
airline industry have brought the bundling issue into sharp focus. In recent years, airlines
have unbundled key elements of the product they offer, introducing separate charges
for in-flight food and for checked baggage, services that were previously included in the
ticket price. In addition to being obvious to millions of fliers, this product unbundling
has received widespread coverage in the press, with the reports typically highlighting
passenger unhappiness with the new bag fees.2
The new fees, especially the charges for checked baggage, have generated a sub-
stantial amount of revenue for the airlines. Data provided by Bureau of Transportation
Statistics (2010) show that airlines collected approximately $2.5 billion in bag fees in
2009 and $3.5 billion in 2012. Although the typical observer might view this new source
of revenue as a windfall for airlines, economists would think twice before reaching such
a conclusion. The typical $20 fee charged for the first checked bag represents an increase
in the effective fare for those passengers who pay it, amounting to a 10% increase over
a typical fare of $200, measured on a one-way basis. If airlines lack the pricing power to
impose such an increase in the cost of travel, economic theory suggests that they would
have had to cut base fares in offsetting fashion when imposing “first bag” fees.3
The possibility that the adoption of bag fees may put downward pressure on base
fares seems to have entirely been overlooked in the voluminous popular discussions of
the new fees. Airlines, of course, never announced any bag-fee-related fare reductions,
but the carriers have ample opportunity to quietly reduce fares via their yield man-
agement systems by allowing more tickets in the cheapest fare classes to be sold. The
purpose of this paper is to explore this possible connection between airline fares and bag
fees, both theoretically and empirically. The paper begins by developing a theoretical
model that portrays an airline’s profit-maximizing choices of both the base fare and the
bag fee. The model predicts that bag fees lead to a decline in the base fare. Although this
fare decline can be viewed as a natural outcome, establishing the result theoretically is
not straightforward. The prediction is then tested empirically, using detailed fare data
from the U.S. Department of Transportation (DOT). The empirical results confirm the
theoretical prediction, with an airline’s average fare falling when it starts collecting a
bag fee, but by less than the amount of the fee.4Given the rarity of empirical work
on the effects of product unbundling, these empirical results are highly noteworthy. In
addition, the findings are distinguished by their focus on a visible unbundling event.
The fact that checked-bag service would only be purchased conditional on purchase
of an airline ticket (never being bought on its own) makes a model of “add-ons” the
appropriate analytical framework. Ellison (2005) developed an add-on model, using
Internet service in a hotel room or extended warranties for cars and appliances as
examples, but he assumed that the consumer only learns the price of the add-on when
purchasing the basic product. Although some airline customers may have been taken by
literature argues that a firm can leverage its profit by tying one product to another.Posner (1976) argues that
monopolies have no such incentives because they unprofitably lose the flexibility to adapt some prices under
a tie-in. However, Tirole (1988) shows that monopolies should set the prices of complementary products to
lower levels than would two independent firms. Davis and Murphy (2000) use this argument to argue that
Microsoft followed a profitable path in setting Internet Explorer’s price to zero.Whinston (1990) demonstrates
that tie-ins could deter entry in a dynamic setting where they are irreversible.
2. See, for example, “More consumers pack lighter,smarter to save when flying”, USA Today, June 1, 2010.
3. Fees for second checked bags were adopted prior to those for first checked bags. However,only a small
share of domestic passengers checks two pieces of luggage.
4. Some individual fare reductions, however,could exceed the amount of the bag fee, an outcome that is
shown to be theoretically possible.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT