Product Innovation Incentives: Monopoly vs. Competition

AuthorYongmin Chen,Marius Schwartz
Date01 September 2013
Published date01 September 2013
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jems.12026
Product Innovation Incentives: Monopoly vs.
Competition
YONGMIN CHEN
Department of Economics
University of Colorado
Boulder CO 80309
yongmin.chen@colorado.edu
MARIUS SCHWARTZ
Department of Economics
Georgetown University
Washington D.C. 20057
mariusschwartz@mac.com
In contrast to Arrow’s result for process innovations, we show that the gain from a product
innovation can be larger to a securemonopolist than to a rivalrous firm that would face competition
from independent sellers of the old product. A monopolist incurs profit diversion from its old
good but may gain more than a rivalrous firm on the new good by coordinating the prices. In a
Hotelling framework, we find simple conditions for the monopolist’s gain to be larger. We also
explain why the ranking of innovation incentives differs under vertical product differentiation.
1. Introduction
Does initial market power dilute a firm’s incentive to invest in substitute new tech-
nologies in order to protect its existing profit? This question has longstanding interest
to policymakers and economists. In a seminal paper, Arrow (1962) showed that a se-
cure monopolist gains less from perfectly patentable process innovations—that lower
the marginal cost of an existing homogeneous product—than would a competitive firm
facing the same market demand. The logic is simple for a drastic innovation—one that
renders the old technology irrelevant. Postinnovation profit will then equal the lower-
cost monopoly level whatever the initial market structure, so the gain from innovation
is lower for an initial monopolist because only it enjoys status quo profit that the in-
novation cannibalizes or “replaces.” If the innovation is nondrastic (the new monopoly
price exceeds the old marginal cost), however, there is an opposing effect: a monopolist
that innovates will earn higher profit postinnovation than would an innovator that faces
competition from the old technology. Nevertheless, Arrow proved that a monopolist’s
gain is lower by using a different argument: the value of a process innovation comes
solely from reducing the firm’s marginal cost and this cost reduction applies to a smaller
output under monopoly than under homogeneous Bertrand competition (see also
Tiro le, 1988).
This output level argument, however, is specific to reductions in marginal cost
for a homogeneous product and leaves the open question: Does Arrow’s ranking of
We thank Axel Anderson, Tim Brennan, Malcom Coate, Jim Dana, Andrew Daughety, Jorge Fernandez, Ian
Gale, Richard Gilbert, Ed Green, David Malueg, Federico Mini, David Sappington, Daniel Vincent,Scott Wall-
sten, Greg Werden,Ralph Winter, anonymous referees, and the Editor for helpful discussions and comments.
C2013 Wiley Periodicals, Inc.
Journal of Economics & Management Strategy, Volume22, Number 3, Fall 2013, 513–528
514 Journal of Economics & Management Strategy
innovation incentives across market structures extend to nondrastic product innovations,
where the new good is a differentiatedsubstitute for the initial good and does not entirely
displace it? Our main finding is that the ranking can be reversed—the incentive to
undertake substitute product innovations can be stronger for a monopolist.1Compared
to a rivalrous firm, a monopolist adding a substitute product will divert profit from its
old product, but may gain more from the new product by coordinating the two prices.
We show that the coordination effect can dominate.
Specifically, our model compares a firm’s incentive to add a new product Bunder
three alternative market structures, where the firm’s gain is denoted in parentheses:
secure Monopoly (Gm)—a monopolist controls product Aand only that same firm can add
B;ex post Duopoly (Gd)—a monopolist controls product Abut only a different firm can
add B; and perfect Competition (Gc)—product Ais supplied by homogeneous Bertrand
rivals (Arrow’s case), and any firm can add B. One motivation for these comparisons
is that policy interventions can alter the market structure and, hence, the innovation
incentive, as under the following scenarios.
Merger Scenario: Suppose producers of good Aare competitive, only they have the
requisite assets to add product B, and they propose a merger-to-monopoly in A.The
gain from adding Bis Gmif the merger is approved and Gcif the merger is rejected.
Patent Scenario: Good Ais supplied by a monopolist protected by a patent that also
blocks innovation in B. If the patent is retained, the innovation incentive is Gm;ifitis
voided, market Abecomes competitive, and the innovation incentive changes to Gc.
Regulation Scenario: Suppose there is a durable franchise monopolist in Aand the
policy choice is between (i) granting that firm also the monopoly rights over a competing
future product B, versus (ii) barring that firm from B. Under regime (i), the incumbent
is unconcerned with preemption in B,soitsgainfromaddingBis given by Gm; under
regime (ii), only an entrant can innovate in B, and its gain is given by its profit under ex
post duopoly,Gd. Option (ii) may be motivated by a (correct) concern that the incumbent
would price the new product higher than would an entrant.
We represent product differentiation as horizontal, following the classic frame-
work of Hotelling (1929; see also Tirole, 1988), adapted to allow asymmetries: products
Aand Bcan differ in their “qualities”—their value to consumers gross of transport
costs—or (equivalently for modeling purposes) in their marginal costs. We show that
Gm>Gdif and only if the new product has higher quality than the old, and that
Gm>Gcalways holds. Thus, the incentive for product innovation can be greater under
secure monopoly than under market structures that admit product market rivalry.
In some such cases, overall welfare also is higher under monopoly. Of course, these
findings should not be construed as advocating monopoly since our analysis abstracts
from various potential inefficiencies of monopoly, such as internal slack (Raith, 2003;
Schmidt, 1997). The results merely caution against sweeping claims that monopoly
invariably undermines product innovation.
Our model purposely omits several important factors discussed in the literature
that can influence relative innovation incentives under alternative market structures,
such as imperfect patent protection, the stochastic natureof R&D outcomes, and scope for
follow-on innovations. (See, for example, Vickers, 2010; Gilbert, 2006; Reinganum,
1989;Tirole,1988.) We retain Arrow’s environment of perfect patent protection and a
1. We assume the new product is a substitute instead of a complement for the initial good because
the view that a monopolist resists innovation to protect its initial profit presumes substitute technologies.
(A complementary new technology would enhance rather than devalue the old one.)

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT