Private Information and Bargaining Power in Venture Capital Financing

AuthorMichael J. Rebello,Yrjö Koskinen,Jun Wang
Published date01 December 2014
Date01 December 2014
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jems.12072
Private Information and Bargaining Power in
Venture Capital Financing
YRJ ¨
OKOSKINEN
The Wharton School
University of Pennsylvania
Philadelphia, PA19104
yrjo@wharton.upenn.edu
MICHAEL J. REBELLO
Naveen Jindal School of Management
University of Texas at Dallas
Richardson, TX 75080
mrebello@utdallas.edu
JUN WANG
Department of Economics and Finance
Baruch College
New York,NY 10010
Jun_Wang@baruch.cuny.edu
We model the natural evolution of private information over the life of a venture capitalist financed
project. In the early stages, the entrepreneur is better informed regarding the project, and when
the project matures, the venture capitalist has an informational advantage over the entrepreneur.
Within this framework, we examine how the venture capitalist’srelative bargaining power affects
cash flow rights and investment. When the bargaining advantage lies with the entrepreneur,
the project may not be screened, and the venture capitalist may acquiesce to excessive initial
investment but subsequently terminate the project. Increased venture capitalist bargainingpower
encourages project screening, attenuates the incentive to overinvest, and reduces the incidence
of project termination subsequent to the initial investment. The payoff sensitivity of venture
capitalist’s financing contract also increases as his bargaining power improves.
1. Introduction
Entrepreneurs are likely to be better informed than venture capitalists about some as-
pects of their projects whereas venture capitalists are likely to be better informed about
others.1Therefore, both venture capitalists and entrepreneurs have to contend with
adverse selection during their negotiations. Although adverse selection is a constant
The authors thank the coeditor, two anonymous referees, Mike Fishman, Thomas Telemann, Mark Johnson,
Josh Lerner, Tom Noe, Merih Sevilir, Masako Ueda, and seminar participants at Boston University, Georgia
Tech,Helsinki School of Economics, Louisiana State University, Simon Fraser University, Southern Methodist
University,University of Minnesota, University of South Carolina, University of Texas at Dallas, University of
Wisconsin - Madison, WakeForest University, University of Colorado at Boulder,the 17th Annual Conference
on Financial Economics and Accounting in Atlanta, and Searle Center Symposium on Economics and Law of
the Entrepreneur in Chicago for their comments. Michael Rebello thanks SIFR for its hospitality during his
visit to Stockholm when he started working on this paper.The authors are responsible for all remaining errors.
1. The evidence in Kaplan and Str ¨
omberg (2003, 2004) suggests that control structures in ventures
are engineered to limit problems arising from both the informational advantage of entrepreneurs and the
C2014 Wiley Periodicals, Inc.
Journal of Economics & Management Strategy, Volume23, Number 4, Winter 2014, 743–775
744 Journal of Economics & Management Strategy
feature of the environment in which venture financing is contracted, other features of
the environment fluctuate. One important feature of the contracting environment that
fluctuates significantly is the flow of capital into venture funds.2This variation in the
flow of capital has been linked to dramatic fluctuations in the generosity of the terms of
venture financing contracts. For example, Gompers and Lerner (2000, 2004) document
that, when a lot of capital flows into venture funds, venture capitalists appear to be un-
der intense pressure to invest in projects: they tend to supply capital at generous terms,
giving rise to the “money chasing deals” phenomenon that leads to increased cash flow
shares for the entrepreneurs.
Recognizing the important influence of adverse selection on venture financing,
researchers have devoted considerable attention to understanding its influence on the
cash flow rights and other features of venture capital contracts. Some have focused
on the optimal design of venture financing contracts when the entrepreneur is better
informed than the venture capitalist while others have examined the effect of reversing
this situation.3However, regardless of their approach to capturing adverse selection
between the entrepreneur and venture capitalist, all these models share a common
feature: they are all built on the assumption that the entrepreneur has an absolute
bargaining advantage vis-`
a-vis the venture capitalist. Therefore, these models are unable
to help us to understand how fluctuations in the pressure on venture capitalists to invest,
by changing the strength of their bargaining position in negotiations over the division
of a project’s surplus, will alter both entrepreneurs’ and venture capitalists’ incentives
to exploit their informational advantages.
To fill this void, we build a model where the outcome of venture financing is
shaped by both the bargaining positions of venture capitalists and entrepreneurs and
adverse selection between them. In our model, the entrepreneur has an informational
advantage regarding the technology employed in the venture and her project’s likeli-
hood of successful scalability from a technological perspective. The venture capitalist,
in contrast, is better informed about factors that are of great importance in later stages of
projects: the management, marketing, and financial know-how needed to successfully
commercialize a venture. Thus, the locus of information asymmetry switches over the
life of a project.4The allocation of bargaining power between the venture capitalist and
the entrepreneur varies independently of their private information and is determined
by the relative scarcity of venture financing. Following the evidence of Gompers and
Lerner (2000, 2004), inflow of capital to venture funds could be an empirical proxy for
informational advantage of venture capitalists regarding [external] risks. The intense screening of projectsby
venture capitalists is consistent with the view that entrepreneurs have an information advantage over venture
capitalists regarding some aspects of their projects. The idea that venture capitalists are informed investors
is consistent both with Sahlman’s (1990) evidence that venture capitalists specialize in a small number of
industries and thus gain a deep understanding of those industries, and Lerner’s (1995) claim that venture
capitalists work closely with the companies they are financing. Hellmann and Puri (2000) and Bottazzi et al.
(2008) provide evidence supporting the claim that venture capitalists are informed investors.
2. In its survey “Venture capital: Money to burn,” The Economist (May 27, 2000) stated “It is clear that
venture capital has been prone to periods of extreme boom and bust.” In its next survey on the venturecapital
industry (April 3, 2004), “After the drought – Venturecapital,” The Economist claimed that “the money available
for investments in start-up companies slowed to a trickle after the bubble burst.”
3. Dessein (2005) and Trester(1998) develop models where entrepreneurs are better informed than the ven-
ture capitalists, whereas Admati and Pfleiderer (1994) and Ueda (2004) develop models where entrepreneurs
are only better informed than a subset of financiers. Garmaise (2007) develops a model in which the venture
capitalist has an informational advantage over the entrepreneur.
4. Yung (2009) also develops a model where both the entrepreneur and the venture capitalist possess
private information, but does not examine the effects of changes in bargaining power between the venture
capitalist and entrepreneur.
Private Information and Bargaining Power in Venture Capital Financing 745
the relative scarcity of venture financing: when the inflow of capital to venture funds is
large, we would expect the entrepreneur to possess the bargaining power. Alternatively,
venture capitalist experience, proxied by the number of entrepreneurs venture capital-
ists have financed (see, e.g., Bengtsson and Sensoy, 2011), can measure their bargaining
power: venture capitalists that have financed many entrepreneurs will have the upper
hand in bargaining.
We show that many features of optimal venture financing contracts vary greatly
with the allocation of bargaining power. When a venture capitalist has an absolute bar-
gaining advantage over an entrepreneur, the optimal contract minimizes the sensitivity
of the entrepreneur’s claim to project profitability.Granting the venture capitalist equity
or convertible claims that can be exchanged for a greater ownership share of the project
is one way to generate this sort of cash flow pattern. In contrast, when the bargain-
ing advantage shifts to the entrepreneur, the optimal contract ensures that the venture
capitalist’s claim is relatively insensitive to the project’s performance whereas the en-
trepreneur’s claim is very performance sensitive. This can be achieved by giving the
entrepreneur a claim resembling levered equity and the venture capitalist a debt-like
claim that can be converted into relatively modest share of equity.
The optimal investment in the project tends to be distorted in response to the
adverse selection problems. The timing and nature of these distortions varies with the
allocation of bargaining power. When the bargaining advantage lies with the venture
capitalist, investment is distorted only during the later stages of the project, at which
point he is privately informed. In this situation, the venture capitalist typically over-
invests. In contrast, when the bargaining advantage switches to the entrepreneur, both
early and late stage investments may be distorted. In this case, the venture capitalist
typically overinvests during the early stages and underinvests in the later stages.5
Another feature of venture financing that is quite sensitive to shifts in bargaining
power is project screening. When the bargaining advantage lies with the venture capi-
talist, the optimal contract always screens out the entrepreneur if her project is of poor
quality. When the bargaining advantage switches to the entrepreneur, she is often able
to obtain financing even for a poor quality project.6To compensate for this lax screen-
ing, the venture capitalist is more likely to terminate the project at a later stage. This
result explains why venture capitalists are less selective and make relatively large initial
investments in projects during venture financing booms.7
These dramatic variations in the venture financing contracts are the result of
changes in the relative importance of venture capitalist’s and entrepreneur’s adverse
selection problems arising from alterations in their bargaining power. When the ven-
ture capitalist has an absolute bargaining advantage, he can exploit it to limit the en-
trepreneur’s share of the project’s rents. Because the entrepreneur can only receive a
relatively small payout from the project, her potential gain from misrepresenting her
private information is also relatively small. Therefore, the primary force shaping the
venture financing contract is the need to limit the venture capitalist’s incentive to exploit
his private information to capture even more of the project’s value than he can based on
his bargaining advantage alone. In contrast, when the bargaining advantage switches to
5. The intuition behind overinvestment during the early stage of the project is similar to De Meza and
Webb’s (1987)result that borrowers who have good prospects may signal their type by overinvesting.
6. Manove et al. (2001) find similar results in their study of banking contracts.
7. For example, during the Internet boom, The Economist (May 27, 2000) reported that the venture capital
industry “has become less cautious about valuations and has financed too many competing companies with
dubious business plans.”

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT