Presidential Address: Collateral and Commitment

AuthorPETER M. DEMARZO
Date01 August 2019
Published date01 August 2019
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jofi.12782
The Journal of Finance R
Peter M. DeMarzo
THE JOURNAL OF FINANCE VOL. LXXIV, NO. 4 AUGUST 2019
Presidential Address:
Collateral and Commitment
PETER M. DEMARZO
ABSTRACT
Optimal dynamic capital structure choice is fundamentally a problem of commitment.
In a standard trade-off setting with shareholder-debtholder agency conflicts, full com-
mitment counterfactually predicts the firm would rely almost exclusively on debt fi-
nancing. Conversely, absent commitment a Modigliani-Miller-like value irrelevance
and policy indeterminacy result holds. Thus, the content of dynamic trade-off theory
must depend on the commitment technology. In this context, collateral is valuable as
a low-cost commitment device. Because ex ante optimal commitments are likely to be
suboptimal ex post, observed capital structure dynamics will exhibit hysteresis and
depart significantly from standard predictions.
DESPITE DECADES OF RESEARCH, the determinants of capital structure dy-
namics remain elusive. The traditional trade-off and pecking-order theoreti-
cal frameworks provide primarily static predictions that are unable to explain
much of the observed cross-sectional and time-series variation in leverage.
Capital structure is not static, but rather evolves over time as an aggregation
of sequential decisions in which shareholders have an incentive to act strategi-
cally,maximizing the share price at the potential expense of creditors. I analyze
a setting in which investors anticipate this behavior and set prices accordingly.
Building on related work, I demonstrate that when trade is frequent, this price
feedback is sufficient to destroy all benefits from leverage. Optimal dynamic
capital structure thus becomes, fundamentally, a commitment problem. View-
ing it through this lens provides new insights into the dynamics of leverage, its
impact on firm valuation, and especially the importance and value of collateral
and alternative commitment technologies.
My goal in this address is to demonstrate why commitment must be a pri-
mary determinant of capital structure. Specifically, in a standard trade-off
model I show that when the firm cannot commit to its future capital structure
Peter DeMarzo is at the Stanford University Graduate School of Business and NBER. This
Presidential Address was delivered to the American Finance Association at the annual meeting in
Atlanta, January 5, 2019. I am grateful to Anat Admati, Jonathan Berk, David Bizer, Philip Bond,
Doug Diamond, Darrell Duffie, Mike Fishman, Zhiguo He, Martin Hellwig, Stefan Nagel, Paul
Pfleiderer, Adriano Rampini, Andy Skrzypacz, Fabrice Tourre, Branko Uroˇ
sevi´
c, and Jeff Zwiebel
for their comments, suggestions, and collaborations. I thank Dan Luo for research assistance, and
Kau’ilani DeMarzo for helpful discussions and endless patience. I hereby declare that, under the
Journal of Finance’s disclosure guidelines, I have nothing to disclose.
DOI: 10.1111/jofi.12782
1587
1588 The Journal of Finance R
choices, the optimal leverage policy is indeterminate and does not benefit cur-
rent shareholders, providing a Modigliani-Miller-like irrelevance result even
in the presence of tax benefits and other standard frictions. Thus, to capture
the potential benefits of leverage, firms must commit ex ante to constrain their
future choices. These constraints imply that observed capital structures will
be both path dependent and ex post inefficient. As a result, similar firms may
have very dissimilar leverage levels and dynamics, even when both are be-
having optimally. In this context, collateral endogenously emerges as a critical
determinant of capital structure because of its commitment value.
To demonstrate these results, I develop a simple stylized model in which tax
benefits and/or pricing differentials (due to liquidity or market segmentation)
provide potential valuation gains from the use of leverage. These gains must be
balanced against the investment distortions and default costs associated with
excessive leverage. In other words, the model represents a standard trade-off
setting.
In standard static trade-off theory, capital structure is a one-time decision
made at the birth of the firm. In that context, there exists a unique optimal debt
level that the firm should choose. Much of the empirical literature on capital
structure seeks to explain the variation in actual firm leverage based on com-
parative statics from such a model. In a dynamic context, however, the static
predictions of trade-off theory do not apply. Moreover, equilibrium outcomes
depend almost entirely on the commitment technology available to firms. At
one extreme, suppose that the firm can commit ex ante to its future lever-
age decisions. Then, by committing to reduce leverage whenever profitability
declines, the firm can avoid the expected costs of financial distress. In other
words, the “trade-off” of the trade-off theory disappears, and full commitment
implies the following counterfactual prediction: firms should be almost exclu-
sively debt financed and avoid default via a commitment to issue equity and
quickly deleverage in the event of a downturn.1
At the other extreme, suppose that the firm cannot commit ex ante, and in-
stead actively manages its capital structure at each point in time to maximize
the firm’s share price. In this case the leverage ratchet effect, highlighted in
Admati et al. (2018), implies that firms will never choose to actively reduce
leverage.2Instead, they would prefer to issue new debt even when doing so
would be detrimental to total firm value. In anticipation, creditors raise their
required yield even when leverage is low, making debt issuance less attractive.
Drawing on the methodology in DeMarzo and He (2019) and DeMarzo, He,
and Tourre (2019) (hereafter, DH19 and DHT19), I show that when the firm
borrows using unsecured debt, this behavior fully dissipates any funding cost
advantages of debt. In particular, although the firm actively manages lever-
age toward a target level, the expected rate of debt issuance raises the credit
1In theory, with full commitment default should never occur unless the firm’s value drops
instantaneously to the point of insolvency. In practice, firm value declines gradually, with firms
often increasing their total indebtedness during the period leading up to bankruptcy.
2See also Bulow and Rogoff (1991) and Bizer and DeMarzo (1992) for related results in the
context of sovereign or individual borrowing.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT