Precautionary Savings with Risky Assets: When Cash Is Not Cash

AuthorCHRISTOPHER HRDLICKA,THOMAS GILBERT,JARRAD HARFORD,RAN DUCHIN
Published date01 April 2017
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jofi.12490
Date01 April 2017
THE JOURNAL OF FINANCE VOL. LXXII, NO. 2 APRIL 2017
Precautionary Savings with Risky Assets: When
Cash Is Not Cash
RAN DUCHIN, THOMAS GILBERT, JARRAD HARFORD,
and CHRISTOPHER HRDLICKA
ABSTRACT
U.S. industrial firms invest heavily in noncash, risky financial assets such as cor-
porate debt, equity, and mortgage-backed securities. Risky assets represent 40% of
firms’ financial portfolios, or 6% of total book assets. We present a formal model to
assess the optimality of this behavior. Consistent with the model, risky assets are
concentrated in financially unconstrained firms holding large financial portfolios, are
held by poorly governed firms, and are discounted by 13% to 22% compared to safe
assets. We conclude that this activity represents an unregulated asset management
industry of more than $1.5 trillion, questioning the traditional boundaries of nonfi-
nancial firms.
AKEY ASSUMPTION IN STUDIES of corporate cash holdings is that industrial firms
invest in actual cash or risk-free, near-cash securities. Recent anecdotal evi-
dence in the press, however, suggests that corporate treasuries have consider-
ably broadened the scope of securities in which they invest. For example, the
article “Google’s Latest Launch: Its Own Trading Floor,” published in Business
Week Online on May 27, 2010, reports that “Google, it turns out, has launched a
trading floor to manage its $26.5 billion in cash and short-term investments .. .
One of the company’s goals is to improve the returns on its money, which until
now has been managed conservatively.”
All authors are at the Michael G. Foster School of Business, University of Washington. We
are grateful to two anonymous referees, an Associate Editor, Michael Roberts (the Editor), David
Cordova (tax partner at Deloitte), Harry DeAngelo, Dave Denis, Amy Dittmar, Mike Faulkender,
Laurent Fresard, Ron Giammarino, Todd Gormley, Jay Hartzell, Carolin Pflueger, Lee Pinkowitz,
Bill Resler, Martin Schmalz, Terry Shevlin, Jake Thornock, and Jeff Zwiebel for insightful dis-
cussions and comments. We thank Aaron Burt, Harvey Cheong, Matthew Denes, John Hackney,
Lucas Perin, and especially Rory Ernst for excellent research assistance. We also thank seminar
participants at Carnegie Mellon, City University–Hong Kong, Emory University, Erasmus Uni-
versity, the Interdisciplinary Center Herzliya(IDC), the University of Amsterdam, the University
of Copenhagen, the University of Hong Kong, the University of Kentucky, the University of Utah,
Tilburg University,Tulane University, and WashingtonUniversity in St. Louis and participants of
the ASU Sonoran Winter Finance Conference 2014, the 9th Annual FIRS meetings, the 2014 SFS
Cavalcade, the Pacific Northwest Finance Conference, the 2014 LBS Summer Finance Symposium,
and the 2014 Western Finance Association Meetings for helpful comments. The authors declare
that they have no potential conflicts of interest, as identified in the Journal of Finance Disclosure
Policy, and have received no outside financial support for the research and writing of this paper.
DOI: 10.1111/jofi.12490
793
794 The Journal of Finance R
In this paper, we investigate both empirically and theoretically the compo-
sition, determinants, and implications of financial assets held by nonfinancial
firms. We show that firms hold large portfolios, which comprise a wide range of
financial assets. Apple, for example, holds $121 billion, or 70% of its book as-
sets, in financial assets, placing it among the largest hedge funds in the world.
Collectively, the firms in our sample manage over $1.5 trillion in financial
assets. Despite the similarity to the traditional asset management industry,
the regulation and disclosure requirements of this shadow asset management
industry are minimal.
Our empirical analysis exploits the implementation of Statement of Financial
Accounting Standards (SFAS)No. 157 in 2009, which requires all firms to report
the fair value of major asset classes on their balance sheet.1We collect data
on firms’ nonoperating financial assets that comprise: (1) the balance sheet
accounts “cash and cash equivalents” and “short-term investments,” which
constitute Compustat’s data item CHE, the standard measure of cash holdings
in the literature, and (2) any additional financial assets reported as “long-term
investments” or “other assets,” not considered by prior studies.2We hand-
collect these detailed data on the asset classes that constitute firms’ financial
portfolios from the footnotes of annual reports for all industrial firms in the
S&P500 Index from 2009 to 2012.
Our findings shed new light on both the size and the composition of indus-
trial firms’ financial asset holdings. First, we find that the total value of firms’
financial asset portfolio is 24.6% larger than the traditional measure of cor-
porate cash holdings. This difference stems from the inclusion of long-term
financial assets. Critically, the existing cash literature has implicitly ignored
these financial assets, which can be held to fund real investment opportunities
and mitigate adverse shocks that may arise in the more distant future.
Second, our estimates indicate that firms invest heavily in noncash securi-
ties that are both risky and illiquid. These securities are frequently included
in the balance sheet accounts “cash and cash equivalents” and “short-term in-
vestments,” which make up CHE. This traditional measure of cash holdings is
composed of at least 23.2% risky securities on average.
Third, we show that risky securities represent 38.3% of aggregate financial
asset portfolios, or 5.8% (5.6%) of the aggregate book value (market value of
equity) of industrial firms in the S&P 500 Index. The vast majority of risky se-
curities (roughly 79%) are also illiquid. They include a wide array of securities,
such as corporate debt (23.6%), equity (8.6%), asset-backed or mortgage-backed
securities (8.4%), and government debt excluding U.S. Treasuries (15.3%),
both domestic and foreign. In contrast, safe assets, which represent 61.7%
of aggregate portfolios, comprise money-like securities with minimal risk and
1See paragraph 32 of SFAS No. 157, paragraph 19 of SFAS No. 115, and Appendix Afor more
information.
2We exclude restricted assets, pension assets, and deferred executive compensation since they
can be viewed as operating assets invested in a particular project or labor payments. We also
exclude derivative hedging, which is studied extensively in a separate literature (e.g., Guay and
Kothari (2003) and Jin and Jorion (2006)).
Precautionary Savings with Risky Assets 795
illiquidity: time deposits, bank deposits, money market funds, commercial pa-
per, and U.S. Treasury securities.
Toassess the motivations and optimality of this behavior, we present a formal
model of a firm’s demand for risky or illiquid financial assets. The model is
a parsimonious representation of a dynamic problem in which the firm has
both present and future real investment projects, and in which the firm has
limited access to external finance. The model can be viewed as an extension of
standard cash models such as Almeida, Campello, and Weisbach (2004). The
main innovation in the model is allowing firms to invest in an array of financial
assets, which include liquid and illiquid assets as well as safe and risky assets.
The model delivers several predictions. First, investing in illiquid or risky
financial assets is suboptimal for financially constrained firms. Second, finan-
cially unconstrained firms benefit from having access to illiquid financial assets
and are at best indifferent to investing in risky financial assets. Importantly,
firms become increasingly indifferent to investing in risky assets as their fi-
nancial portfolios grow. Consequently, firms with larger portfolios invest more
in risky assets and exhibit higher variation in their portfolio allocations. Third,
an additional layer of agency problems or managerial overconfidence may tilt
firms toward investing more in risky financial assets. Fourth, there are no
uniform tax incentives to invest in risky financial assets.
Our empirical findings are consistent with the predictions of our theory. We
find that both risky and illiquid financial asset holdings increase substantially
as the firm becomes more financially unconstrained and holds a larger finan-
cial asset portfolio. Our univariate estimates indicate that firms in the lowest
portfolio size quintile invest 10% of their portfolio in risky securities, whereas
firms in the top quintile invest 40% of their portfolio in risky securities. Fur-
ther, the variation in portfolio allocation within the top size quintiles is also
significantly higher.
We find similar results in multivariate regressions. To mitigate endogene-
ity concerns about the joint determination of the size and composition of the
financial asset portfolio, we provide estimates from a two-stage least squares
(2SLS) model, which exploits unexpected operating cash flow innovations. Our
2SLS estimates suggest that an increase of one percentage point in the size of
the asset portfolio leads to an increase of 30 basis points in the portion of the
portfolio invested in risky assets.
Having established the link between the size of the asset portfolio and its
composition, we investigate the effects of additional firm- and manager-level
attributes. Our estimates reveal a number of systematic patterns. First, consis-
tent with Opler et al. (1999) and Bates, Kahle, and Stulz (2009), the size of the
asset portfolio increases in firm-level proxies for the demand for precautionary
savings, such as cash flow volatility, investment opportunities, and firm size.
In contrast, holding constant the size of the asset portfolio, risky financial as-
sets are concentrated in large, low cash-flow volatility firms, with only average
investment opportunities. These findings are consistent with the prediction
that more financially constrained firms, with a stronger precautionary savings
motive, will avoid risky financial assets.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT