Precarious Investments and Blame Gaming – Adverse Effects and the Inherent Danger of Simplification

Published date01 August 2016
AuthorLevi Gårseth‐Nesbakk,Frode Kjærland
Date01 August 2016
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/faam.12097
Financial Accountability & Management, 32(3), August 2016, 0267-4424
Precarious Investments and Blame
Gaming – Adverse Effects and the
Inherent Danger of Simplification
LEVI G˚
ARSETH-NESBAKK AND FRODE KJÆRLAND
Abstract: This blame game study reports on attempts by eight municipalities
to recover money in the wake of financial losses resulting from the financial crisis.
Actor-network theory helps unravel which actors were involved in creating the blame
game and those who were mobilized to facilitate it, which resulted in judicial losses
and substantial advisory service fees. The evidence suggests that punctualization
can be costly when dealing with precarious investments and engaging in blame
gaming, as simplifications might evoke adverse effects. Contributions relate to group
formation and the use of experts in blame gaming and addressing related strategies
as heterogeneous network effects.
Keywords: financial crisis, municipalities, blame game, punctualization, actor-
network theory
INTRODUCTION
People and organizations seek to avoid blame (Douglas, 1992; Hood, 2007 and
2011; and Weaver, 1986). They may do so by limiting or deflecting blame, by
formally allocating or transferring the (organizational) responsibility to a third
party, or by preventive means, such as reducing or avoiding actions that might
lead to the instigation of blame. The result is a blame game (henceforth BG)
in which multiple players attempt to pin the responsibility for misfortune on
The authors are PhDs and Associate Professors at Nord University Business School, Norway,
and Trondheim Business School, NTNU, Norwegian University of Science and Technology,
Trondheim, Norway. They wish to acknowledge the helpful and constructive comments
provided by two anonymous reviewers. In addition, they are thankful for comments made
by participants at the 14th biennial CIGAR conference in Birmingham, UK, 2 - 3 September,
2013 and a workshop organized by Trondheim Business School, Oppdal, Norway, 9 - 11
October, 2013.
Address for correspondence: Levi G˚
arseth-Nesbakk, Nord University Business School,
Norway, 8049 Bodø, Norway.
e-mail: levi.garseth-nesbakk@nord.no
C
2016 John Wiley & Sons Ltd 281
282 G˚
ARSETH-NESBAKK AND KJÆRLAND
one another. The point of departure is nevertheless the perception of avoidable
losses or harm and the associated responsibility or wrongdoing (Hood, 2011).
The global financial crisis resulted in considerable losses and harm, in addition
to discussions about associated responsibilities and wrongdoing (i.e., staging a
grand BG). Blinder (2013) explores factors that conspired to create the financial
crisis and concludes that although it is tempting, the blame cannot be associated
with a single villain because in events as complex as the multifaceted financial
crisis, several factors are typically at (inter)play. Fox (2008) and Mortreuil (2010)
reach a similar conclusion.
The recent financial crisis originated from a bubble in the US housing market
(Blinder, 2013) and involved large financial institutions (Claessens et. al., 2010),
such as Citigroup and AIG (Blinder, 2013). Subprime loans were pushed onto
buyers without a sound assessment of their ability to repay (Schiller, 2008).
These mortgages were subsequently turned into complex securitized products
and sold on the global market. However, what had appeared to be solid (AAA-
rated) investments turned out to be precarious investments, ‘a fragile house of
cards’ (Blinders, 2013, p. 84). These investments were not safe or stable. Rather,
they were dependent on uncertain and increasingly gloomy circumstances, and
perhaps even unknown conditions. In 2007 and beyond, the true precarious
nature of these products became known, and the financial markets plummeted.
The financial crisis quickly spread, particularly in and following 2007, eventually
affecting the world economy.
This turmoil intertwined the public and the private sector via direct losses
on financial investments made by the public sector. Other affinities included
the public sector’s regulatory function and market interventions that were
implemented to prevent a larger crisis from emerging (Blinder, 2013). In
the public debate, most attention has been focused on the macroeconomic
level in seeking to find regulatory solutions to the financial problems or in
depicting scapegoats (Fox, 2008). Complex financial investment products (e.g.,
collateralized debt obligations) were challenging to comprehend for most —
if not all — investors (Blinder, 2013). Smaller investors, including smaller
municipalities, were therefore likely to find them particularly opaque. In recent
years, local governments have ended up in financial trouble due to insufficient
financial expertise (Deal et al., 2009). For example, losses suffered by Norwegian
municipalities on investments in complex CDOs that were brought about by
the financial crisis have led to studies that sought to detail how the losses and
investments came about (Pani and Holman, 2014) and/or to examine the reach of
the financial crisis (Aalbers, 2009). What remains unexplored is what vulnerable
small municipalities do when they are criticized or feeling duped after having
lost a fortune on investments in complex financial products. When they blame
others for their misfortune, while attempting to redeem their money, how do
they go about it?
After all, blaming is a ‘necessary precursor for claiming’ something from those
that are being blamed (Hood, 2011, p. 7). A BG is controllable and helps stabilize
C
2016 John Wiley & Sons Ltd

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT