Potential competition and quality disclosure

Date01 November 2019
AuthorFrederick Dongchuhl Oh,Junghum Park
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jems.12326
Published date01 November 2019
J Econ Manage Strat. 2019;28:614630.wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/jems614
|
© 2019 Wiley Periodicals, Inc.
Received: 20 June 2018
|
Revised: 27 May 2019
|
Accepted: 29 May 2019
DOI: 10.1111/jems.12326
ORIGINAL ARTICLE
Potential competition and quality disclosure
Frederick Dongchuhl Oh
1
|
Junghum Park
2
1
KAIST College of Business, Korea
Advanced Institute of Science and
Technology, Seoul, Korea
2
Department of Economics, University of
Essex, Colchester, UK
Correspondence
Frederick Dongchuhl Oh, KAIST College
of Business, Korea Advanced Institute of
Science and Technology, 85 HoegiRo,
DongdaemoonGu, Seoul 02455, Korea.
Email: dcoh415@kaist.ac.kr
Abstract
This study presents a model of quality disclosure in which an incumbent,
through its quality and disclosure choices, influences the potential that a new
entrant enters the market. In this regard, we consider a sequential framework in
which the incumbent chooses its quality and decides whether to disclose it to
the market; subsequently, the entrant makes the same decisions, if it enters the
market. We show that the potential competition can create strategic incentives
for the incumbent to choose nondisclosure, because the availability of
information about the incumbents quality promotes entry by enhancing the
entrants expected profit from the market. In addition, an analysis of the effects
of mandatory disclosure laws suggests that they can be effective in encouraging
new market entrants and in improving the product quality of established firms.
KEYWORDS
mandatory disclosure law, market entry, potential competition, product quality, voluntary
disclosure
JEL CLASSIFICATION
D43; L13; L15
1
|
INTRODUCTION
Firms often have many ways to disclose private information about product quality to consumers without incurring
significant costs. These range from product reviews (e.g., consumer reports) and advertisements to thirdparty
certification. More important, the advent of the Internet significantly enhanced the scope and credibility of seller
information disclosure by providing a platform for consumer reviews (Chen & Xie, 2008). Early analyses of quality
disclosure suggest that complete voluntary disclosure occurs because highquality sellers are always willing to
distinguish themselves from lowquality sellers (Grossman, 1981; Grossman & Hart, 1980). However, voluntary
disclosure does not appear to occur as frequently as this type of theory suggests. The extant marketing literature reports
the lack of product information in advertisements (Abernethy & Butler, 1992; Abernethy & Franke, 1996). The fact that
mandatory disclosure laws affect the industry is also inconsistent with this theory. Examples include hygiene ratings for
restaurants (Jin & Leslie, 2003) and the service quality of health maintenance organizations (Jin, 2005).
1
In addition,
several recent papers attribute nondisclosure behavior to the strategic interaction among firms due to product market
competition. In particular, highquality sellers may decide not to disclose product quality to reduce price competition.
For example, nondisclosure can play a role in differentiating the firmsproducts from rival products (Board, 2009; Hotz
& Xiao, 2013). Further, a highquality firm can use nondisclosure to credibly precommit and not undercut prices, as it
enables the firm to signal quality through higher prices (Janssen & Roy, 2015). However, all of these studies consider
actualcompetition among established firms.
As such, this study considers the effect of potentialcompetition on quality disclosure. Given that a market is often
highly concentrated due to economies of scale, patent protection, the presence of a highly rapid innovator, and so on,
potential competition plays a competitionlike role in restraining firmspricing behavior. In addition, it is wellknown
that potential competition generates an incentive for a monopoly incumbent to deter new competition through a variety
of strategic instruments, such as limit pricing (Milgrom & Roberts, 1982) and capacity commitment (Dixit, 1980), as
well as R&D and advertising (Fudenberg & Tirole, 1984).
2
We extend this longheld idea to answer the question of
whether potential competition affects firmsdisclosure behavior. Our insight is that a potential entrant can use the
incumbents disclosure for its postentry product positioning, thereby promoting its entry, an unfavorable situation for
the incumbent. This creates the incentive for established firms to choose nondisclosure. We illustrate this insight by
considering the case in which a firm chooses its quality and subsequently decides whether or not to disclose it, a
scenario that is new to the literature on quality disclosure.
We develop a simple model of quality disclosure in which an incumbent makes strategic choices on quality and
disclosure to influence the likelihood that a new entry will occur thereafter. We assume that product quality may be
either high or low, and is unalterably once determined, and that consumers differ in their willingness to pay for each
type of quality. At the start of the model, the incumbent chooses its quality and incurs qualitydependent fixed costs.
Then, it decides whether to credibly disclose the quality to the market, which has no direct costs. Next, a potential
entrant decides whether to enter the market and incurs entry costs. Upon deciding to enter, the entrant chooses its
quality and incurs the same qualitydependent fixed costs as does the incumbent. Subsequently, both firms
simultaneously make their postentry disclosure choices. Finally, the firms engage in price competition and earn their
profits accordingly. We assume that a highquality premium exists; that is, a highquality firm earns a higher profit than
does a lowquality firm when these firms compete. This is the case when the fixed cost of choosing high quality is
positive, but sufficiently low.
The main result of this study shows that a unique equilibrium can exist, in which the incumbent does not reveal its
quality to the market before entry occurs. With this equilibrium, the incumbent follows a mixed strategy of quality
choice; hence, the quality may be either high or low. However, the incumbent does not reveal its quality to the market
before entry because the incumbent chooses not to disclose it. Moreover, the entrant uses a mixed strategy for the entry
decision, and therefore may or may not enter the market. Once entry occurs, the incumbent discloses its quality. The
intuition behind the incumbents nondisclosure behavior is that nondisclosure makes it impossible for a potential
entrant to determine the more profitable quality level, thereby deterring entry. We identify the condition under which
this nondisclosure equilibrium exists and show that it corresponds to an intermediate range of entry costs. In this
regard, within a moderate range of entry costs, there is no equilibrium when the incumbent discloses its quality before a
new entry. The results indicate that firms are likely to reduce disclosure and informative advertising when facing entry
threats. Finally, we compare this equilibrium outcome with the case in which there is a mandatory disclosure law. We
find that enforcement leads to the increased potential of a new entrant in the market, as well as a higher expectation of
quality from the incumbent.
Examples that are in line with our results include manufacturing products and products associated with health and
environmental concerns, including the restaurant industry, as in Jin and Leslie (2003). These industries are often
concentrated or segmented by geography or other horizontal attributes such that no major firm has a head start, but
faces a significant threat of new market entrants. Consequently, though the major firm has a significant market share, it
faces significant potential competition due to the possibility that new firms will enter the market by differentiating
themselves enough to survive, thereby taking the major firms market share. Our main result on the incumbents
disclosure behavior explains why existing firms in these industries may be reluctant to voluntarily enhance market
transparency. Indeed, Apple, which some refer to as the first mover in its industry, appears to be reluctant to reveal
detailed specifications for its new phones. Addition, in relation to Jin and Leslies (2003) study, this result helps to
explain why restaurants were reluctant to disclose their hygiene grades before the adoption of mandatory disclosure.
Further, our results explain why disclosure programs affect these industries, and provide a new rationale for mandatory
disclosure laws. Whether these industries indeed face fiercer competition following mandatory information disclosure
or some external improvement in the provision of information on product quality is an interesting question for future
empirical research.
We contribute to the recent literature on product information disclosure by introducing a new explanation for
nondisclosure phenomena, and showing that mandatory disclosure law benefits consumers by promoting competition
among sellers. The literature considers various aspects of firmsdisclosure incentives, indicating the positive and
negative effects of mandatory disclosure laws. While some of these studies suggest that buyerside informational
OH AND PARK
|
615

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT