Political Incentives to Suppress Negative Information: Evidence from Chinese Listed Firms

DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/1475-679X.12071
Date01 May 2015
Published date01 May 2015
DOI: 10.1111/1475-679X.12071
Journal of Accounting Research
Vol. 53 No. 2 May 2015
Printed in U.S.A.
Political Incentives to Suppress
Negative Information: Evidence
from Chinese Listed Firms
JOSEPH D. PIOTROSKI,
T. J. WONG,
AND TIANYU ZHANG
Received 4 January 2012; accepted 24 November 2014
ABSTRACT
This paper tests the proposition that politicians and their affiliated firms (i.e.,
firms operating in their province) temporarily suppress negative information
in response to political incentives. We examine the stock price behavior of
Chinese listed firms around two visible political events—meetings of the Na-
tional Congress of the Chinese Communist Party and promotions of high-
level provincial politicians—that are expected to asymmetrically increase the
costs of releasing bad news. The costs create an incentive for local politicians
and their affiliated firms to temporarily restrict the flow of negative informa-
tion about the companies. The result will be fewer stock price crashes for the
affiliated firms during these event windows, followed by an increase in crashes
after the event. Consistent with these predictions, we find that the affiliated
firms experience a reduction (an increase) in negative stock return skewness
before (after) the event. These effects are strongest in the three-month pe-
riod directly preceding the event, among firms that are more politically con-
nected, and when the province is dominated by faction politics and cronyism.
Additional tests document a significant reduction in published newspaper ar-
ticles about affected firms in advance of these political events, suggestive of a
Stanford University; The Chinese University of Hong Kong.
Accepted by Christian Leuz. The authors thank the Research Grants Council of the Hong
Kong Special Administrative Region, China for a Competitive Earmarked Research Grant No.
CUHK 452708. The authors also thank Katherine Schipper, Ross Watts, and two anonymous
referees for helpful comments and suggestions. An online appendix to this paper can be down-
loaded at http://research.chicagobooth.edu/arc/journal/onlineappendices.aspx.
405
Copyright C, University of Chicago on behalf of the Accounting Research Center,2014
406 J.D.PIOTROSKI,T.J.WONG,AND T.ZHANG
link between our observed stock price behavior and temporary shifts in the
listed firms’ information environment.
JEL codes: G39; M41
Keywords: state ownership; information environment; corporate gover-
nance; political costs; China
1. Introduction
In this paper, we examine the proposition that politicians and their af-
filiated firms (i.e., firms operating in the politician’s province) suppress
negative information in response to incentives created by political events
that temporarily increase the cost of releasing bad news. Prior research ar-
gues that politicians and governments like to avoid negative news about
their activities (e.g., Peltzman [1976], Watts and Zimmerman [1986]). To
the extent that certain events asymmetrically increase the cost of releasing
bad news, local politicians will have a heightened incentive to temporarily
restrict the flow of negative information about firms under their control
or influence. Similarly, self-interested firms reliant on the support of local
politicians will also respond to the incentives created by the political event.
If these temporary incentives are sufficiently strong, the result will be a re-
duced flow of negative information in advance of the events, followed by
an increase in the flow of negative information after the event as previously
suppressed information is subsequently released. For publicly traded com-
panies, the temporary suppression of negative information will generate a
distinct shift in stock price crash behavior around the political event if the
market is unable to fully unravel the suppression of bad news.
We test these arguments by examining the stock price behavior of Chi-
nese listed firms around two highly anticipated political events—meetings
of the National Congress of the Chinese Communist Party (CCP) and pro-
motions of high-level provincial politicians—over the period 1993 to 2011.
We employ a stock price crash methodology specifically designed to capture
the suppression and subsequent release of value-relevant negative informa-
tion (e.g., Chen, Hong, and Stein [2001], Jin and Myers [2006]). We focus
on Chinese listed firms because their information environment is expected
to be sensitive to political incentives for opacity. In China, government
and party officials exert significant influence on listed firms through di-
rect ownership arrangements and/or indirect channels (e.g., bureaucracy,
regulation, licensing requirements, and informal political and social net-
works); this influence creates a conduit by which listed firms are expected
to align their behavior with the preferences of local politicians. We focus on
meetings of the National Congress and provincial-level promotions as these
two events temporarily increase the political costs of revealing bad news.
From a career concerns perspective, local politicians incur a personal cost
when firms under their control report poor performance, as adverse eco-
nomic news limits their advancement within the party structure (e.g., Chen,
POLITICAL INCENTIVES TO SUPPRESS NEGATIVE INFORMATION 407
Li, and Zhou [2005], Li and Zhou [2005]). More generally, authoritarian
governments like China need to demonstrate strengths to stay in power
(e.g., Tullock [1987]). The revelation of bad news about Chinese firms and
their political supervisors reveals weaknesses, disrupts the government’s
narrative, and impacts social harmony. In both cases, the revelation of bad
news is very costly to both local politicians and their affiliated firms during
these event windows, generating a heightened incentive to suppress nega-
tive information. Finally, China’s institutional arrangements, such as weak
regulatory enforcement, limited private enforcement opportunities, con-
centrated ownership structures, and relationship-based contracting, may
be insufficient to support the necessary incentives for transparency during
these periods.
However, there exist countervailing forces capable of sheltering listed
firms from these transitory political pressures. First, the conversion of state
enterprises to joint stock companies and their subsequent listing on stock
exchanges expose state-controlled firms to western governance mecha-
nisms and market forces that demand transparency. Second, the Chinese
government also set up the State Asset Supervision and Administration
Commission to further decentralize control power from central and lo-
cal governments to the listed firms. Qian [1996] and Fan, Wong, and
Zhang [2013] argue that the Chinese government has established struc-
tural wedges between politicians and listed firms to credibly commit to
not intervene in these firms’ day-to-day operations. Third, suppression of
negative information is inherently difficult. Successful suppression requires
politicians to have control over an array of information dissemination and
production mechanisms that prevent self-interested market participants
and competing politicians from leaking negative information. Finally, the
market could interpret silence during political periods as bad news; this un-
raveling would eliminate the expected political benefits of suppression. To
the extent that these factors effectively mitigate the influence of local politi-
cians’ incentives for opacity, we should not observe Chinese listed firms
responding to transitory pressures to suppress bad news around political
events. More generally, we expect firms most (least) exposed to strong mar-
ket (political) forces, such as firms with weak political connections, non-
state-owned firms, or firms operating in market-oriented provinces or in
provinces without powerful local politicians, to be less sensitive to transi-
tory political incentives.
Consistent with the bad news suppression predictions, we find that af-
filiated listed firms are significantly less (more) likely to experience stock
price crashes in advance of (after) our two political events. Mirroring the
theoretical predictions of Chen, Hong, and Stein [2001], this intertempo-
ral pattern is consistent with the initial suppression, and subsequent release,
of adverse news in response to the heightened incentives of the local politi-
cians and affiliated firms. These results are robust to alternative empirical
specifications and various empirical measures of stock price crash behavior
and information flow (including stock price synchronicity). Our evidence

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT