Political corruption shielding and corporate acquisitions

AuthorLawrence Kryzanowski,Ashrafee Tanvir Hossain
Date01 February 2021
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/fire.12247
Published date01 February 2021
DOI: 10.1111/fire.12247
ORIGINAL ARTICLE
Political corruption shielding and corporate
acquisitions
Ashrafee Tanvir Hossain1Lawrence Kryzanowski2
1Faculty of Business Administration,
Memorial University of Newfoundland, St.
John’s, Newfoundland and Labrador,Canada
2Department of Finance, John Molson School
of Business, Concordia University,Montreal,
Quebec, Canada
Correspondence
LawrenceKryzanowski, Department of
Finance,John Molson School of Business,
ConcordiaUniversity, 1455 de Maisonneuve
BlvdWest, Montreal, QC H3G 1M8.
Email:lawrence.kryzanowski@concordia.ca
Fundinginformation
SeniorConcordia University Research Chair
inFinance; Memorial University of Newfound-
land;Social Sciences and Humanities Research
Councilof Canada, Grant/Award Number:
435-2018-048
Abstract
Corruption includes rent-seeking behavior by public offi-
cials (e.g., lavish in-kind benefits and monetary kickbacks
for contracts/permits/regulatoryleniency, improper political
contributions/support, etc.) that can negatively affect firm
valuations, performances, and strategic choices. Shielding
strategies are used to diminish rent-seeking attractiveness
of firms. Acquisitions provide a better channel than cash or
leverage for assessing the wealth effects of shielding strate-
gies. We find that the mean 3-day announcement returns
for acquirers for a large sample of U.S. domestic acquisitions
between 1990 and 2014 is significantly lower for firms head-
quartered in relatively higher corruption states. Our results
survive an array of robustness tests.
KEYWORDS
M&As, political corruption, political favor(s), shielding, state and
local government
JEL CLASSIFICATION
D73, G30, G34, H70
1INTRODUCTION
Political corruption (“corruption”henceforth) has a long historical footprint. Based on World Bank Enterprise Surveys
(http://www.enterprisesurveys.org/data/exploretopics/corruption), one in five companies worldwide receive at least
one request for a bribe payment, and almost one out of three are expected to provide gifts to secure government
contracts. Though giving or taking bribes is not legally allowed in the United States, rent-seeking behavior bycorrupt
politicians and public officials continues to flourish, arguably in a more sophisticated manner.The best and worst rank-
ing achieved by the United States over a 10-year period (2009–2018) using the Corruption PerceptionsIndex (CPI)
published by TransparencyInternational is 16th in 2015 and 2017, and 24th in 2011, respectively.
Financial Review. 2021;56:55–83. wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/fire ©2020 The Eastern Finance Association 55
56 HOSSAIN ANDKRYZANOWSKI
Studies show that corruption can havenet negative effects if political corruption merely represents a harmful form
of taxation without compensating benefits (Shleifer & Vishny, 1993), which, in turn, can negatively affect the valua-
tions, performances, and strategic choices of firms (e.g., Brown, Smith, White, & Zutter, 2019; Dass, Nanda, & Xiao,
2016; Hossain & Kryzanowski, 2020; Shleifer & Vishny,1993;Smith,2016).1Although this literature generally relates
political corruption with ex ante political connections, we follow the literature and use various ex ante and ex post
measures of political corruption, such as for enforcement (attempted or actual convictions), political codes of ethics,
and perceptions of interested observerssuch as the media that can vary geographically (e.g., Dass et al., 2016; Parsons,
Sulaeman, & Titman, 2018;Smith,2016).
Corruption includes rent-seeking either initiated or agreed to by public officials or employees. This rent-seeking
includes the solicitation or acceptance of lavish in-kind benefits and monetary kickbacks for the granting of contracts
or permits or licenses, for taking a particular position on a specific piece of legislation such as the imposition of tariffs
that favors a firm’s industry from foreign competition, and regulatory or tax leniency.It also includes requests for or
acceptances of improper monetary and in-kind political contributions. An exampleis a rent-seeking conviction in 2014
that was later vacated in 2016 by the United States Supreme Court.2This case involved Robert McDonnell, a former
governor of Virginia, and his wife for accepting more than $170,000 in loans and gifts (e.g., Rolex watch, vacations,
partial payments for a daughter’s wedding reception) from the CEO of Star Scientific who wanted state universitiesto
perform important clinical tests on a dietary supplement developed by the company (Barnes, 2016). Shielding strate-
gies such as low cash, high leverage, relocation to a jurisdiction with lower political corruption, and acquisitions are
used to make firms less attractive to rent seekersby increasing firms bargaining power with rent seekers (Svensson,
2003). As rent seekers tend to target firms based on their capacity to pay(Stulz, 2005), firms are less attractive if they
reduce their current liquidity through lower cash balances or their future discretionary liquidity by increasing cash-
flow commitments through increased leverage or distribute their revenue-generatingassets over multiple locations.
Firms also are less attractive for rent seekers if theyacquire other firms with cash or debt financing or in other juris-
dictions with lower political corruption.
Although Smith (2016) identifies four channels by which firms could shield against political rent-seeking (cash
balances, leverage, relocations, and acquisitions), his evidence was essentially confined to a robust demonstration
that firms have lower cash balances and higher leveragesin more corrupt environments, which is indirectly consistent
with their use to shield against rent-seeking. However, Smith does not provide evidenceon the effect on firm value
of using lower cash balances and higher leverages in more corrupt environments. Our paper provides a further test
of Smith’s Shielding Hypothesis against rent-seeking using the channel of acquisitions, which provides a convenient
test of firm-value effects. Specifically, we investigate whether local (state-level) political corruption affects the
shareholder wealth of acquirers as reflected in announcement period returns (cumulative abnormal returns [CARs]).
Our analyses are grounded in two associated expectations. First, if a rational manager in a corrupt environment
uses acquisitions as a tool to shield against rent-seeking, they will do so as long as the net benefit of shielding
is positive; therefore, we expect that the CARs for corrupt-place acquirers will be positive. Second, the market-
assessed net benefits of acquisitions reflected in acquirer CARs in more corrupt environments due to the lower
bargaining power of the acquirer (e.g., due to less “informational transparency” as found by Dass et al., 2016) should
be lower than that for acquirers in less corrupt environments. Tosummarize, we expect that an average high-corrupt-
place acquirer experiences a nonnegative return that will be lower than its average low-corrupt-place acquirer
counterpart.
1Some studies find benefits of illegal behavior, which maynot be explicit, by political participants if firms can deal in a more cost-effective manner with
bureaucratic rules or rent-seeking (e.g.,Borisov, Goldman, & Gupta, 2016; Faccio, Masulis, & McConnell, 2006; Khwaja & Mian, 2005). Rent seekers aim to
obtainfinancial gains and/or benefits by altering the distribution of economic resources.
2The Court’s decision on page 28 stated that: “There is no doubt that this case is distasteful; it maybe worse than that. But our concern is not with tawdry
talesof Ferraris, Rolexes, and ball gowns. It is instead with the broader legal implications of the Government’s boundless interpretation of the federal bribery
statute.”McDonnell v. United States, 579 U.S. ___(2016).

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT