Political contestability and public contract rigidity: An analysis of procurement contracts

Published date01 April 2019
Date01 April 2019
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jems.12268
AuthorMarian W. Moszoro,Jean Beuve,Stéphane Saussier
316 © 2018 Wiley Periodicals, Inc. wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/jems J Econ Manage Strat. 2019;28:316–335.
Received: 21 June 2017 Revised: 20 February 2018 Accepted: 31 May 2018
DOI: 10.1111/jems.12268
ORIGINAL ARTICLE
Political contestability and public contract rigidity: An analysis
of procurement contracts
Jean Beuve1Marian W. Moszoro2Stéphane Saussier3
1Department of Economics, Université Paris 1
Panthéon-Sorbonne, Paris, France
2George Mason University,Fairfax, Virginia
and WarsawSchool of Economics, Poland
3Department of Economics, IAE-Sorbonne
Business School, Paris, France
Correspondence
Marian W.Moszoro, Department of Eco-
nomics,George Mason University, 3434 Wash-
ingtonBlvd, Arlington, VA 22201, USA.
Email:mmoszoro@gmu.edu
Abstract
Are public contracts less adaptable than private contracts? Using a comprehensive
set of contracts for a standard product, we compare procurement contracts in which
the procurer is either a public administration or a private corporation. We find that
public-to-private contracts feature more rigidity clauses than private-to-private con-
tracts and that the use of rigidity clauses in public contracts rises when political risks
are more salient. We argue that a significant part of the increased rigidity of public
contracts is a contractual adaptation to limit political hazards from political opponents
and interested third parties.
KEYWORDS
contractual rigidity, political contestability, procurement
JEL CLASSIFICATION:
D23, D72, D73, D78, H57
1INTRODUCTION
Understanding public contracting is of utmost relevance for economists and policymakers: Public procurement accounts for
approximately 10% of GDP in the United States and 12% of GDP in OECD member countries.1Public contracting is the
government activity most vulnerable to waste and corruption, and its efficiency is a substantial component of voters' political
choices.
Prior studies have primarily assessed the efficiency of public contracting by focusing on the proper scope of governments
and whether contracting public services to the private sector is more efficient than direct public management. Despite several
explanations attributing transaction costs to the inefficiency of public contracting (Brown & Potoski, 2003), further explanations
for such inefficiencies haveremained obscure.2Little has been done, however, to examine the juxtaposition between the intrinsic
natures of public sector and private sector contracting. The prevailing view is that private sector contracts encapsulate most
contractual complexities (general case), whereas public sector contracts present special cases of issues rooted in social equity,
corruption, and “red tape.” That is, public sector and private sector contracts have been studied extensively in their separate
domains, but there exists no overarching theory that explains the idiosyncrasies of public vis-à-vis private contracts. This gap is
due, in part, to the difficulty in comparing contractual objects across public and private spheres.
We thank the participants in the presentations made at Columbia University (ALEA), University of California, Berkeley(Law & Economics), George Mason
University (Econ), Duke University(ISNIE), Sorbonne Business School (Chaire EPPP), Université Paris-Dauphine, Universitat Autònoma de Barcelona, Uni-
versidad de Chile (CEA), and the University of Bristol for their comments. Weare also par ticularlyindebted to Ken Ayotte, Lisa Bernstein, Nicholas Bloom,
John de Figueiredo, Rui de Figueiredo, Ronald Fischer, Robert Gibbons, Ricard Gil, Scott Masten,John Morgan, Kathr yn Plata, Eric Rasmusen, Pablo Spiller,
and Eric Talley for thorough comments and helpful suggestions.
BEUVE ET AL.3
317
A fundamental feature of public contracts is that they are subject to public oversight because they deal with public monies
(Spiller, 2008). As argued by Moszoro and Spiller (2018), public contracts are characterized by intrinsic differences stemming
from a substantial amount of supervision and control by political opponents and interest groups, who hold a stake in challeng-
ing and disrupting a contractual relationship. Consequently, unlike private contracting, a grasp on politics becomes vital in
understanding public contracting.
Public contracting is awarded through a set of rule-based (bureaucratic) procedures. This “contract rigidity” refers to the
addition of contractual specifications that impose ex post stringent enforcement, intolerance to adaptation, and penalties for
deviation.3From the public administration perspective, contractual rigidity minimizes the risk of politically motivated challenges
(Moszoro & Spiller, 2018). While from the contractor's perspective, contractual rigidity minimizes the risk of governmental
opportunism (Moszoro & Spiller, 2014), to include unfair administrative treatment and creeping expropriation.
Moreover,when faced with unexpected circumstances, private contractees tend to adapt ad hoc, while formalized amendments
are often found in public contracts. The rigidity of public contracts triggered by third-party opportunism also induces their
renegotiation through written amendments.
Building on the aforementioned characteristics of public contracting, two testable propositions can be derived. First, public
contracts are more rigid than equivalent transactions governed under private contracting. Second, public authorities subject to
political competition increase the proceduralization of contractual agreements to insulate themselves from politicallymotivated
challenges.
To test these propositions, we collected a unique set of contracts concerning parking lot agreements signed between 1985
and 2009 in France. We analyzed a large sample of contractual arrangements signed between a private operator and 24 private
procurers (which we call “private contracts”) and between the same private operator and 132 public authorities (which we call
“public contracts”) for which we were able to gather data on local elections.
Analogous to Schwartz and Watson(2012), we parsed through this rich sample of contracts using textual analysis. We find that
public contracts feature more rigidity clauses. We further compare the subsample of public contracts and find that the frequency
of rigidity clauses rises when political competition is tight. We argue that a significant part of the differences in contractual rigid-
ity among private and public contracts is a political risk adaptation to mitigate challenges from political contesters and interest
groups. Complementarily, where firms anticipate a politically unstable environment that may lead to creeping expropriation,
they will require rigid terms to minimize governmental opportunism.4
Our study contributes to contract theory and organizational economics by testing a novel set of propositions based on hazards
faced by public sector procurers. Organizations that are characterized by high degrees of “publicness” differ from “private”
organizations because they are more permeable to the political environment (Meier & O'Toole, 2011; Ring & Perry, 1985).
In this paper, we empirically test this permeability, focusing on the degree of contractual rigidity. The corollary is that the
perceived inefficiency of public contracting is mostly the result of contractual adaptation to different inherent hazards and thus
is not directly remediable (Williamson, 1999).
In most democracies, politicians face similar hazards in public procurement which—in addition to legal indictments in court—
refer foremost topolitical challenges that affect their reputation, career, and payoffs. Thus, our setup and results are generalizable
to jurisdictions with different legal systems (e.g., civil and common law). Wealso provide a replicable protocol to assess contract
rigidity in politically competitive jurisdictions.
The paper is organized as follows:In Section 2, we return to the specificities of public contracting and third-par ty opportunism
and derive propositions concerning rigidity and political contestability of public contracts. In Section 3, we present our data
and our empirical strategy to test our propositions. In Section 4, we show the results of our tests and robustness checks. In
Section 5, we utilize a natural experiment involvinga change in public procurement scrutiny to show the causal effect of political
contestability to contract rigidity. In Section 6, we discuss the results and limitations of our study. Section 7 concludes.
2THE SPECIFIC NATURE OF PUBLIC CONTRACTS
When contracting complex objectives (e.g., uncertain quality or unpredictable future events), the survival of a contract may be
at risk. One way to deal with contract complexity is to rely on informal commitments, that is, relational contracting (Macaulay,
1963).5To rely on relational contracts in the public domain is unfeasible. As Spiller (2008) points out, “when faced with unfore-
seen or unexpected circumstances, private contractees, as long as the relation remains worthwhile, adjust their required per-
formance without the need for costly renegotiation or formal re-contracting. Public contracting, on the other hand, seems to
be characterized by formalized, standardized, bureaucratic, rigid procedures.” Public contracting generates peculiar hazards
associated with one of the procurers being subject to public scrutiny to avoid corruption and graft.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT