Political Connections and Allocative Distortions

Date01 April 2019
AuthorDAVID SCHOENHERR
Published date01 April 2019
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jofi.12751
THE JOURNAL OF FINANCE VOL. LXXIV, NO. 2 APRIL 2019
Political Connections and Allocative Distortions
DAVID SCHOENHERR
ABSTRACT
Exploiting a unique institutional setting in Korea, this paper documents that politi-
cians can increase the amount of government resources allocated through their social
networks to the benefit of private firms connected to these networks. After winning
the election, the new president appoints members of his networks as CEOs of state-
owned firms that act as intermediaries in allocating government contracts to private
firms. In turn, these state firms allocate significantly more procurement contracts
to private firms with a CEO from the same network. Contracts allocated to con-
nected private firms are executed systematically worse and exhibit more frequent cost
increases through renegotiations.
AGROWING LITERATURE DOCUMENTS A positive relationship between political
connections and firm value for a large set of countries,1providing evidence
of different benefits that accrue to politically connected firms.2While this
David Schoenherr is at Princeton University.I am deeply grateful to my advisor Vikrant Vig for
his generous and invaluable guidance. I thank Pat Akey, Taylor Begley, Joao Cocco, James Dow,
Alex Edmans, Julian Franks, Mireia Gine, Francisco Gomes, John Griffin, Rainer Haselmann,
Samuli Kn¨
upfer, Ralph Koijen, Ilyana Kuziemko, Megan Lawrence, Mina Lee, Stefan Lewellen,
Jean-Marie Meier, Atif Mian, Todd Mitton, Kasper Nielsen, Gen-Ichiro Okamoto, Elias Papaioan-
nou, Megha Patnaik, Tarun Ramadorai, Ville Rantala, Amit Seru (the Editor), Henri Servaes,
Rui Silva, Janis Skrastins, Jan Starmans, Ahmed Tahoun, an anonymous Assistant Editor and
two anonymous referees; seminar participants at Boston College, Duke University,the Federal Re-
serve Board, the Hong Kong University of Science and Technology, IESE Business School, INSEAD,
London Business School, Princeton University, Stanford University, UC Berkeley, the University
of Chicago, the University of Colorado Boulder, the University of Pennsylvania, Vienna Univer-
sity, and Washington University at St. Louis; and conference participants at the 2018 American
Finance Association, the 27th Australasian Finance and Banking Conference and PhD Forum,
the 2015 European Economic Association Meeting, the 2015 European Finance Association Doc-
toral Tutorial,the 2017 Financial Intermediation Research Society Meeting, the 14th Transatlantic
Doctoral Conference, and the 2016 Western Finance Association Meeting for their many helpful
comments and suggestions. I declare that I have not received significant financial support related
to the research described in this paper.
1See Roberts (1990), Fisman (2001), Johnson and Mitton (2003), Jayachandran (2006), Faccio
(2006), Ferguson and Voth (2008), Bunkanawanicha and Wiwattanakantang (2009), Faccio and
Parsley (2009), Goldman, Rocholl, and So (2009), Cooper, Gulen, and Ovtchinnikov (2010), Amore
and Bennedsen (2013), Akey (2015), Acemoglu et al. (2016), and Acemoglu, Hassan, and Tahoun
(2018).
2In particular,the literature shows that politically connected firms have better access to finance
(Khwaja and Mian (2005), Leuz and Oberholzer-Gee (2006), Claessens, Feijen, and Laeven (2008),
Li et al. (2008)), are more likely to receive government funds, bail-outs, and contracts (Faccio,
DOI: 10.1111/jofi.12751
543
544 The Journal of Finance R
relationship has been widely documented, however, evidence on the under-
lying mechanisms is scarce. On the one hand, public officers who control
the allocation of government resources may abuse their power and trans-
fer rents to connected firms at the expense of allocative efficiency. On the
other hand, to the extent that connections help mitigate frictions such as
information asymmetries or moral hazard problems, public officers may be
able to better allocate resources through connected firms. Given the large
amount of resources allocated by governments,3a thorough understanding
of the underlying mechanisms is important, as alternative mechanisms have
different implications for economic efficiency and in turn different policy
implications.
In this paper, I exploit a unique institutional setting and detailed microlevel
data on public procurement contract allocation in Korea to explore an impor-
tant mechanism through which firms benefit from political connections and
its implications for allocative efficiency. In Korea, the president has the au-
thority to appoint the CEOs of state-owned firms. These state firms play an
important role as intermediaries in allocating public procurement contracts to
private firms. Following his election in 2007, the new president, Lee Myung
Bak, appointed a large number of people from two of his networks—alumni
from Korea University Business School (KU network) and former executives
of Hyundai Engineering & Construction (HEC network), the firm he worked
for before going into politics, as CEOs in many state firms. Private firms with
a CEO from one of the president’s networks thus suddenly became connected
to a large number of state firms with a newly appointed CEO from the same
network.
Examining changes in public procurement contract allocation around the
election, I find that private firms connected to the new president’s networks
experience a significant increase in their annual public procurement contract
volume, equal to 3% of the firms’ assets, after the election.4Cross-sectional vari-
ation in connectedness to different state firms allows me to compare changes in
contract allocation to the same private firm at a given point in time (firm-time
fixed effects). I find that the increase in contract volume is driven by those state
firms in which the president appointed a CEO from the same network. This
suggests that private firms benefit from the appointment of state firm CEOs
from the same network.
Masulis, and McConnell (2006), Duchin and Sosyura (2012), Cingano and Pinotti (2013), Goldman,
Rocholl, and So (2013), Tahoun (2014), Baltrunaite (2018), Brogaard, Denes, and Duchin (2017)),
and avoid compliance with regulations (Fisman and Wang (2015)).
3Public procurement contracts alone account for 10% to 20% of GDP in developed countries
(OECD (2015)).
4Private firms connected to Lee Myung Bak’s networks experience 2.21 (4.45) percentage point
higher returns than nonconnected firms the day (week) after his nomination as his party’s presi-
dential candidate in a close election. This amounts to 8.51% of connected firms’ combined market
value, and 0.63% of total KOSPI (Korea’s main stock market index) market capitalization. The
additional contracts allocated to connected private firms explain about 20% of the increase in
connected firms’ market value.
Political Connections and Allocative Distortions 545
While private firms connected to the president’s networks benefit from the
appointment of connected state firm CEOs, higher allocation of government
contracts from state firms to private firms with a CEO from the same net-
work is not limited to the new president’s networks. Exploiting information on
CEOs’ educational background, I find that private firms generally experience
an increase in contract volume from state firms that they become connected to
through their CEO’s alumni network. Additionally, private firms with a CEO
from the KU network do not experience an increase in contract volume from
state firms in which the new president appointed a CEO from the KU network
if that state firm already had a CEO from the KU network before the election.
Together these results suggest that private firms receive more government
contracts due to their CEO’s connections to state firm CEOs, regardless of con-
nections to the president. The president’s role in benefiting firms connected to
his networks is to increase the number of state firm CEOs from his networks.
These results document an important mechanism through which politicians
benefit connected firms: the authority to appoint people to important positions
allows politicians to increase the amount of government resources allocated
through their networks.
Next, I examine how connections between state firm and private firm CEOs
affect the efficiency of contract allocation. An increase in procurement con-
tracts allocated to connected firms would be consistent with a benign role of
connections in mitigating frictions, but also a malign role of connections in
distorting resource allocation. For example, state firm CEOs may have better
information about people from their network, which would allow them to bet-
ter allocate contracts within the network (Cohen, Frazzini, and Malloy (2008),
Conley and Udry (2010)), or may be better able to monitor connected firms
and resolve problems that occur during contract execution through a social
collateral channel (Kandori (1992), Guiso, Sapienza, and Zingales (2004), Am-
brus, M¨
obius, and Szeidl (2014)). Alternatively, state firm CEOs may extend
preferential treatment to connected firms, allocating contracts to these firms
even if they are not able to execute these contracts effectively (Banerjee and
Munshi (2004), Hwang and Kim (2009), Haselmann, Schoenherr, and Vig
(2018)). Understanding which of these forces dominates is important, as they
have different implications for the optimality of network connections between
representatives of government entities and private firms, and hence lead to
different policy implications.
Comparing the execution of contracts allocated to the same private firm by
connected and nonconnected state firms allows me to assess how connections
affect allocative efficiency. Data on contract amendments, including informa-
tion on contract performance (delays, financial problems, construction mis-
takes, etc.), are available for all construction contracts. After the election, the
performance of contracts allocated to connected private firms deteriorates sig-
nificantly relative to the performance of contracts allocated to nonconnected
firms. Contracts allocated to connected firms are about 10 percentage points
more likely to exhibit adverse outcomes. In addition, construction costs in-
crease about 5 percentage points more often for contracts allocated to connected

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT